Balkinization   |
Balkinization
Balkinization Symposiums: A Continuing List                                                                E-mail: Jack Balkin: jackbalkin at yahoo.com Bruce Ackerman bruce.ackerman at yale.edu Ian Ayres ian.ayres at yale.edu Corey Brettschneider corey_brettschneider at brown.edu Mary Dudziak mary.l.dudziak at emory.edu Joey Fishkin joey.fishkin at gmail.com Heather Gerken heather.gerken at yale.edu Abbe Gluck abbe.gluck at yale.edu Mark Graber mgraber at law.umaryland.edu Stephen Griffin sgriffin at tulane.edu Jonathan Hafetz jonathan.hafetz at shu.edu Jeremy Kessler jkessler at law.columbia.edu Andrew Koppelman akoppelman at law.northwestern.edu Marty Lederman msl46 at law.georgetown.edu Sanford Levinson slevinson at law.utexas.edu David Luban david.luban at gmail.com Gerard Magliocca gmaglioc at iupui.edu Jason Mazzone mazzonej at illinois.edu Linda McClain lmcclain at bu.edu John Mikhail mikhail at law.georgetown.edu Frank Pasquale pasquale.frank at gmail.com Nate Persily npersily at gmail.com Michael Stokes Paulsen michaelstokespaulsen at gmail.com Deborah Pearlstein dpearlst at yu.edu Rick Pildes rick.pildes at nyu.edu David Pozen dpozen at law.columbia.edu Richard Primus raprimus at umich.edu K. Sabeel Rahmansabeel.rahman at brooklaw.edu Alice Ristroph alice.ristroph at shu.edu Neil Siegel siegel at law.duke.edu David Super david.super at law.georgetown.edu Brian Tamanaha btamanaha at wulaw.wustl.edu Nelson Tebbe nelson.tebbe at brooklaw.edu Mark Tushnet mtushnet at law.harvard.edu Adam Winkler winkler at ucla.edu Compendium of posts on Hobby Lobby and related cases The Anti-Torture Memos: Balkinization Posts on Torture, Interrogation, Detention, War Powers, and OLC The Anti-Torture Memos (arranged by topic) Recent Posts Setting the Agenda, Part III
|
Tuesday, June 19, 2007
Setting the Agenda, Part III
Heather K. Gerken
Setting the Agenda for Scholarship on Election Reform
Comments:
There is a dynamic you have left out (at least, so far)--a first mover problem. No state whose population tends to identify, on the national level, with a certain party will want to unilaterally disarm and give votes to the other party.
Take a state that is majority Democrat, like California. If I were a Californian (I am now, but was not then, but nevermind) and a Democrat, would I have wanted the reform proposal the Governor put forward? I know that the effect of this would probably be to increase Republican representation in the U.S. House (since California's legislature is Democratic, I presume they have been gerrymandering in favor of Democrats). I know, however, that other sites of notorious gerrymandering in favor of Republicans--whether Texas or Pennsylvania--will not be doing likewise. We have a prisoner's dilemma here. Thus, even if my commitment to election reform were stronger than my commitment to party, or to other ideological goals that my party can advance, I would still choose no reform. I would not agree to this proposal, even if I were willing to agree to a national anti-gerrymandering proposal that nonetheless cost my side votes. Indeed, doing so unilaterally actually makes the national government more undemocratic, since at least now Democratic gerrymandering in California offsets Republican gerrymandering in Ohio. If Californians stop gerrymandering, but Republicans in Ohio continue to do so, One wonders if California and Ohio had teamed up, what they could have accomplished. California has been largely Democratic the last few elections; Ohio, while not as Republican as CA is Democratic, was nonetheless considerably more red up until recently. Perhaps each could have made their proposal take effect only upon the other's adoption of reform. The FairVote recognizes this problem. There is no way Colorado is going to abandon the winner-take-all-electors system unilaterally, for it would mean no candidate would waste a dime there ever again. California would not, simply because it would mean a massive number of electors going to Republicans; Texas likewise to Democrats (30% of Texans would still yield 10 electors, easily enough to have made the difference in 2000). The FairVote takes effect only after enough states are on board for it to achieve its goals. I wonder the degree to which even a citizens' commission would be subject to these temptations. A random sampling of Californians would still come up with a majority of Democrats. Obviously, this only has to do with national politics--the effect is weaker within a state. Nonetheless, this is one of the biggest here-to-there obstacles that I foresee: a problem not merely of politicians self-interest, but of politically minded voters in our federal system.
Who, after all, is going to claim that a randomly chosen body of voters is undemocratic or that everyday citizens have a partisan axe to grind?
Not me -- but then, unless this is literally some kind of jury selection system, will this really be a "randomly chosen body of voters"? Surely there will either be some kind of self selection for "reform activists", some kind of "friends of Governor X" history, or most likely both. Nothing terribly wrong with that, but I think it wouldn't be quite as immune to political sniping as you suggest. Or do you actually have a random, jury-like process in mind here? Don't mean to nitpick, but I think this needs some clarification.
Re FairVote, actually the same "unilateral disarmament" arguments apply, they're just made less obvious .
If Californians suspect Ohioans or Wyomingans(?) are running strong voter suppression or election machine fraud systems, they might reconsider throwing their electoral college votes away on the bonfire of a national popular vote system that is, overall, less fair than their own. NPV/FairVote/whatever depends crucially, I think, on federalized, vigorously enforced voter registration and election procedures, but this doesn't seem to be acknowledged by its proponents. Personally, I rather like the electoral college per se, it's just badly apportioned; a simple tweak (removing the 2 senatorial electors per state) would be an adequate reform. Yes, that would take an amendment and probably a miracle; but so should NPV's corollary requirements, properly understood.
Taking up the Dr. Gerken's "here to there" idea, though, and in an effort to be positive about the National Popular Vote/FairVote scheme: maybe NPV would be a catalyst for anti-vote suppression legislation and uniform voter registration procedures (or vice versa).
HR 811 (HAVA reform: audited elections, no black box voting machines) may be the other part of the puzzle, in that it acknowledges the need for a uniform federal election process.
[One] problem is that the election system quickly dissolves into a prisoner’s dilemma for voters. As voters cannot really determine the true impact of any particular legislator’s corruption on their job performance, they will systematically undervalue the possibility of a candidate being corrupt unless they can find some other signal within the candidate’s campaign donations that can separate corrupt candidates from non-corrupt ones. . . . [S]uch a signal cannot generally be gleamed from the campaign finance disclosures. Thus, other attributes of the candidate, which make better-funded candidates more attractive to voters than lesser-funded candidates almost entirely irrespective of whether the candidate is corrupt, dominate the voter’s decision-making process. Since a candidate’s openness to corruption increases their ability to obtain campaign funds, the result is that the candidates themselves are systematically encouraged to permit corrupt quid pro quo donations. As a result, legislators, even though they would prefer to be free of corruption, are thus required to act corruptly in order to maintain office. . . .
Taking this further, for each individual lawmaker, voters cannot accurately grasp what each donor’s contribution received for their vote, nor the cost to them of that decision. They may know that a candidate who receives large sums of campaign contributions year after year is more likely to result in overall corruption, but unless the candidate can show that these donations came from such small amounts that it would be impossible for the legislator to show that the donors received nothing for their contributions. Furthermore, the information costs of trying to figure out which donors are more likely to result in corrupt behavior is too high to become an effective source of information for the voter. Without actually understanding the real effect of corruption on the legislative process, the result is that voters simply have normative Without actually understanding the real effect of corruption on the legislative process, the result is that voters simply have normative views of contributors based on preset political preferences. As Strauss argues, “[b]oth [civil rights groups and the agricultural lobby] are well organized groups. Both purport to be concerned with the good of society and to be trying to implement a vision of social justice, not just promoting their own selfish interest.”
Looking at the expertise experienced gerrymanderers exercise, compared to the naivete mere citizens are likely to exhibit, is to contemplate the same difficult chasm between status quo and future egalitarianism in voting.
In CA the dynamic was far from the characterization of unpopularity of Schwarzenegger. The initiative which placed the redistricting measure on the 2005 special election ballot was largely fueled by two sources, both out of state: the measure was funded in part by Schwarzenegger fundraising conducted among wealthies in places such as TX and WADC; and the measure was cookiecutter from the Republican Party strategy book which is based upon expert analysis of how to game the initiative systems in states with robust feedback loops in intrastate politics. In CA in 2005, further, the legislature was so worried about the initiative's duplicitous advertising that the lawmakers began to offer compromise to the governor, suggesting a majority party weighting formula as an overlay upon the Republican National Party template for balancing CA elections by handing to retirees from the bench the responsibility for studying and redrawing district boundaries. In CA this empirically meant the pool of candidates for the redistricting commission consisted mostly of Republican elderly men, as CA has a penchant for having Republicans as governor, although often the legislature is Democratic Party led; so the retirees appointed predominantly would be judges appointed by people like Ron Reagan, George Deukmejian, Pete Wilson, Arnold Schwarzenegger. At present the same Democratic Party leaders in-state who offered that sop to Schwarzenegger are engaged in placing a next generation version of that compromise on the next ballot in 2008. I tend to back the stridency of the political process, and like the fact incumbents can rule on how much money they can fundraise and the way their cloackroom deals map their political futures' mutual security. One of the problems with intransigence in this matter, though, is its fostering of a pretty much one party system of government; it is a partisanism which draws its bounds, however, at the most controversial issues; for example, when a president's administration steps over the traditional line of keeping political plum appointments strategies separate from key institutional positions and departments where the civil service bureaucracy has functioned best when kept as apolitical as possible. In sum, we will vote when we see the risk the status quo's upset will usher in something more abusive. I certainly want expertise on a citizen redistricting committee, not some trial by peers voir dire approach to keeping informed and involved persons from membership in such a body. My view is leadership of character is the great apotheosis in the political process; a state which elects an elections official with great insight and drive, as CA did in 2006 in electing then state senator D.Bowen as Secretary of State to oversee elections policies, gives itself the best chance to develop foolproof elections systems, and to diminish the influence of subterfuging plotters and simple charlatans who would subvert elections processes for personal or organizational ends. Guarantee my vote will be counted, and that the canvassing software is honest, the results auditable; bring the most eloquent and informed advocates into the public forum and provide ample documentation including online links, so I may become educated in issues which apply to all of us. From this beginning come yet more candidates of character. I think it is possible to address this topic looking at either CA or OH, and without rehashing the OH2006 election, or the fates of some of the principals who assured its outcomes, or the postmortems in print and online which describe the raw politics that was practiced in that election in OH. We have yet to witness a complete rollout of the corrupting effects of the US attorney purges which played out in elections across the US, and clearly those purges were part of an election law savvy strategy; what's worse, the bosses who designed the strategy continue to work in high office. It will be nice to work on these matters in legislatures; and academia needs to develop the intellectual tools to serve the process. I definitely do not support the idea of blue ribbon commissions having the functional equivalency of elected representatives. A vote is a vote and the news is what people talk about a lot. We can accomplish much locally in vote related matters; let the federal government take its cues from what develops in the states. I would be interested in hearing what other observers have to say about the depictions here, of national political strategies having local components. And I wonder who has found a transcript of FEC appointed commissioner von Spakovsky's nomination hearing last week online, though I know video is available, if one has a certain manufacturer's software on one's workstation. We need to be cognizant that the president is nominating to key posts individuals who made a reputation for politicizing voting as a substitute for now illegal processes, and that the DoJ has obliterated most of the apolitical experts from its reviewing section responsible for overseeing vote disputes. There are institutional barriers right now to introducing more fairness into voting law. I look forward to this series' next installment.
Thomas Nephew: Unless this is literally some kind of jury selection system, will this really be a "randomly chosen body of voters"?
One tested and proven mechanism is spelled out in some detail here. In brief, citizens selected at random from from the voter registration list could opt out, either for lack of time or lack of interest, but no one could opt in. There are two major limitations on the citizens commission idea. First, if it's conclusions are to have maximum legitimacy, the commission needs to be established the government rather than by (for example) the League of Women Voters or Common Cause. This requires that the foxes themselves think it's at least OK. A proposal similar to the British Columbia Citizens' Assembly was introduced in the California Legislature in 2006. Leaders of the majority party didn't even assign it to a committee for a hearing. Second, citizens selected in this way prove -- again, this is now demonstrated in practice -- to be both interested in and good students of some pretty complicated subject matter. But they are entirely at the mercy of their teachers, i.e. the "expert" consultants who are hired to develop materials, design presentations, and generally shape the dialogue. In spite of that, I find the Citizens Assembly idea very, very exciting. But I'm prejudiced. Both of the CA's to date (British Columbia and Ontario) decided in favor of proportional representation, which is what I work on.
I take issue with a couple of the assertions and assumptions in these posts. The notion that the supposed abstraction of reform proposals causes voters to lack interest strikes me as undeveloped and it also cries out for empirical support. In some respects the conjecture may be downright backwards. It may be that the lack of interest in voting reform is merely a reflection of a general lack of interest in voting in this country -- which may in turn be a product of winner take all elections rather than consensus. More fundamentally, voting reform proposals have often tended to suggest very concrete outcomes -- e.g., enfranchising more potential democrats voters. Insofar as this is the case, one might commend the voting public for having a certain amount of suspicion of both politician and academic reformers. If reformers want their proposals to have more traction they should be able to articulate how their proposals address basic issues of fairness. Reformers always face a kind of Rawlsian legitimacy problem if they cannot articulate why they would want to be part of a revised political system without knowing what the outcome would be from reform.
Post a Comment
It is also easy to overstate the consensus on the need for reforms -- particularly with districting. The often accurate popular image of back room deals in smoky rooms makes alternative redistricting practices seem desirable. However, the risks for minority voters of having no representation whatsoever from many proposed reforms is high. To speak the concrete language of a redistricter, it is because districts are often drawn from census blocks rather than tracts that many minority legislators have seats. Bizarrely shaped districts are representative districts, and if this is not the case we need to be able to explain why not. If the only thing that mattered was the median voter then we need not have districts at all, but at large districts, at least within the confines of the two party system, destroy minority voting strength. In sum, gerrymandering is not simply a matter of partisanship, it is a matter of one's vision of democratic representation. Of course, reforms that enhance the individual's access to the vote (apart from issues of dilution) should happen sooner rather than later. I take this to be the focus of the Democracy Index. (Insofar as it is not, there is a real risk that theories of democracy will masquerade as objective data.) Voting, however, is collective action. It would really be a shame if scholars lost the big picture out of mere impatience.
|
Books by Balkinization Bloggers Linda C. McClain and Aziza Ahmed, The Routledge Companion to Gender and COVID-19 (Routledge, 2024) David Pozen, The Constitution of the War on Drugs (Oxford University Press, 2024) Jack M. Balkin, Memory and Authority: The Uses of History in Constitutional Interpretation (Yale University Press, 2024) Mark A. Graber, Punish Treason, Reward Loyalty: The Forgotten Goals of Constitutional Reform after the Civil War (University of Kansas Press, 2023) Jack M. Balkin, What Roe v. Wade Should Have Said: The Nation's Top Legal Experts Rewrite America's Most Controversial Decision - Revised Edition (NYU Press, 2023) Andrew Koppelman, Burning Down the House: How Libertarian Philosophy Was Corrupted by Delusion and Greed (St. Martin’s Press, 2022) Gerard N. Magliocca, Washington's Heir: The Life of Justice Bushrod Washington (Oxford University Press, 2022) Joseph Fishkin and William E. Forbath, The Anti-Oligarchy Constitution: Reconstructing the Economic Foundations of American Democracy (Harvard University Press, 2022) Mark Tushnet and Bojan Bugaric, Power to the People: Constitutionalism in the Age of Populism (Oxford University Press 2021). Mark Philip Bradley and Mary L. Dudziak, eds., Making the Forever War: Marilyn B. Young on the Culture and Politics of American Militarism Culture and Politics in the Cold War and Beyond (University of Massachusetts Press, 2021). Jack M. Balkin, What Obergefell v. Hodges Should Have Said: The Nation's Top Legal Experts Rewrite America's Same-Sex Marriage Decision (Yale University Press, 2020) Frank Pasquale, New Laws of Robotics: Defending Human Expertise in the Age of AI (Belknap Press, 2020) Jack M. Balkin, The Cycles of Constitutional Time (Oxford University Press, 2020) Mark Tushnet, Taking Back the Constitution: Activist Judges and the Next Age of American Law (Yale University Press 2020). Andrew Koppelman, Gay Rights vs. Religious Liberty?: The Unnecessary Conflict (Oxford University Press, 2020) Ezekiel J Emanuel and Abbe R. Gluck, The Trillion Dollar Revolution: How the Affordable Care Act Transformed Politics, Law, and Health Care in America (PublicAffairs, 2020) Linda C. McClain, Who's the Bigot?: Learning from Conflicts over Marriage and Civil Rights Law (Oxford University Press, 2020) Sanford Levinson and Jack M. Balkin, Democracy and Dysfunction (University of Chicago Press, 2019) Sanford Levinson, Written in Stone: Public Monuments in Changing Societies (Duke University Press 2018) Mark A. Graber, Sanford Levinson, and Mark Tushnet, eds., Constitutional Democracy in Crisis? (Oxford University Press 2018) Gerard Magliocca, The Heart of the Constitution: How the Bill of Rights became the Bill of Rights (Oxford University Press, 2018) Cynthia Levinson and Sanford Levinson, Fault Lines in the Constitution: The Framers, Their Fights, and the Flaws that Affect Us Today (Peachtree Publishers, 2017) Brian Z. Tamanaha, A Realistic Theory of Law (Cambridge University Press 2017) Sanford Levinson, Nullification and Secession in Modern Constitutional Thought (University Press of Kansas 2016) Sanford Levinson, An Argument Open to All: Reading The Federalist in the 21st Century (Yale University Press 2015) Stephen M. Griffin, Broken Trust: Dysfunctional Government and Constitutional Reform (University Press of Kansas, 2015) Frank Pasquale, The Black Box Society: The Secret Algorithms That Control Money and Information (Harvard University Press, 2015) Bruce Ackerman, We the People, Volume 3: The Civil Rights Revolution (Harvard University Press, 2014) Balkinization Symposium on We the People, Volume 3: The Civil Rights Revolution Joseph Fishkin, Bottlenecks: A New Theory of Equal Opportunity (Oxford University Press, 2014) Mark A. Graber, A New Introduction to American Constitutionalism (Oxford University Press, 2013) John Mikhail, Elements of Moral Cognition: Rawls' Linguistic Analogy and the Cognitive Science of Moral and Legal Judgment (Cambridge University Press, 2013) Gerard N. Magliocca, American Founding Son: John Bingham and the Invention of the Fourteenth Amendment (New York University Press, 2013) Stephen M. Griffin, Long Wars and the Constitution (Harvard University Press, 2013) Andrew Koppelman, The Tough Luck Constitution and the Assault on Health Care Reform (Oxford University Press, 2013) James E. Fleming and Linda C. McClain, Ordered Liberty: Rights, Responsibilities, and Virtues (Harvard University Press, 2013) Balkinization Symposium on Ordered Liberty: Rights, Responsibilities, and Virtues Andrew Koppelman, Defending American Religious Neutrality (Harvard University Press, 2013) Brian Z. Tamanaha, Failing Law Schools (University of Chicago Press, 2012) Sanford Levinson, Framed: America's 51 Constitutions and the Crisis of Governance (Oxford University Press, 2012) Linda C. McClain and Joanna L. Grossman, Gender Equality: Dimensions of Women's Equal Citizenship (Cambridge University Press, 2012) Mary Dudziak, War Time: An Idea, Its History, Its Consequences (Oxford University Press, 2012) Jack M. Balkin, Living Originalism (Harvard University Press, 2011) Jason Mazzone, Copyfraud and Other Abuses of Intellectual Property Law (Stanford University Press, 2011) Richard W. Garnett and Andrew Koppelman, First Amendment Stories, (Foundation Press 2011) Jack M. Balkin, Constitutional Redemption: Political Faith in an Unjust World (Harvard University Press, 2011) Gerard Magliocca, The Tragedy of William Jennings Bryan: Constitutional Law and the Politics of Backlash (Yale University Press, 2011) Bernard Harcourt, The Illusion of Free Markets: Punishment and the Myth of Natural Order (Harvard University Press, 2010) Bruce Ackerman, The Decline and Fall of the American Republic (Harvard University Press, 2010) Balkinization Symposium on The Decline and Fall of the American Republic Ian Ayres. Carrots and Sticks: Unlock the Power of Incentives to Get Things Done (Bantam Books, 2010) Mark Tushnet, Why the Constitution Matters (Yale University Press 2010) Ian Ayres and Barry Nalebuff: Lifecycle Investing: A New, Safe, and Audacious Way to Improve the Performance of Your Retirement Portfolio (Basic Books, 2010) Jack M. Balkin, The Laws of Change: I Ching and the Philosophy of Life (2d Edition, Sybil Creek Press 2009) Brian Z. Tamanaha, Beyond the Formalist-Realist Divide: The Role of Politics in Judging (Princeton University Press 2009) Andrew Koppelman and Tobias Barrington Wolff, A Right to Discriminate?: How the Case of Boy Scouts of America v. James Dale Warped the Law of Free Association (Yale University Press 2009) Jack M. Balkin and Reva B. Siegel, The Constitution in 2020 (Oxford University Press 2009) Heather K. Gerken, The Democracy Index: Why Our Election System Is Failing and How to Fix It (Princeton University Press 2009) Mary Dudziak, Exporting American Dreams: Thurgood Marshall's African Journey (Oxford University Press 2008) David Luban, Legal Ethics and Human Dignity (Cambridge Univ. Press 2007) Ian Ayres, Super Crunchers: Why Thinking-By-Numbers is the New Way to be Smart (Bantam 2007) Jack M. Balkin, James Grimmelmann, Eddan Katz, Nimrod Kozlovski, Shlomit Wagman and Tal Zarsky, eds., Cybercrime: Digital Cops in a Networked Environment (N.Y.U. Press 2007) Jack M. Balkin and Beth Simone Noveck, The State of Play: Law, Games, and Virtual Worlds (N.Y.U. Press 2006) Andrew Koppelman, Same Sex, Different States: When Same-Sex Marriages Cross State Lines (Yale University Press 2006) Brian Tamanaha, Law as a Means to an End (Cambridge University Press 2006) Sanford Levinson, Our Undemocratic Constitution (Oxford University Press 2006) Mark Graber, Dred Scott and the Problem of Constitutional Evil (Cambridge University Press 2006) Jack M. Balkin, ed., What Roe v. Wade Should Have Said (N.Y.U. Press 2005) Sanford Levinson, ed., Torture: A Collection (Oxford University Press 2004) Balkin.com homepage Bibliography Conlaw.net Cultural Software Writings Opeds The Information Society Project BrownvBoard.com Useful Links Syllabi and Exams |