Balkinization   |
Balkinization
Balkinization Symposiums: A Continuing List                                                                E-mail: Jack Balkin: jackbalkin at yahoo.com Bruce Ackerman bruce.ackerman at yale.edu Ian Ayres ian.ayres at yale.edu Corey Brettschneider corey_brettschneider at brown.edu Mary Dudziak mary.l.dudziak at emory.edu Joey Fishkin joey.fishkin at gmail.com Heather Gerken heather.gerken at yale.edu Abbe Gluck abbe.gluck at yale.edu Mark Graber mgraber at law.umaryland.edu Stephen Griffin sgriffin at tulane.edu Jonathan Hafetz jonathan.hafetz at shu.edu Jeremy Kessler jkessler at law.columbia.edu Andrew Koppelman akoppelman at law.northwestern.edu Marty Lederman msl46 at law.georgetown.edu Sanford Levinson slevinson at law.utexas.edu David Luban david.luban at gmail.com Gerard Magliocca gmaglioc at iupui.edu Jason Mazzone mazzonej at illinois.edu Linda McClain lmcclain at bu.edu John Mikhail mikhail at law.georgetown.edu Frank Pasquale pasquale.frank at gmail.com Nate Persily npersily at gmail.com Michael Stokes Paulsen michaelstokespaulsen at gmail.com Deborah Pearlstein dpearlst at yu.edu Rick Pildes rick.pildes at nyu.edu David Pozen dpozen at law.columbia.edu Richard Primus raprimus at umich.edu K. Sabeel Rahmansabeel.rahman at brooklaw.edu Alice Ristroph alice.ristroph at shu.edu Neil Siegel siegel at law.duke.edu David Super david.super at law.georgetown.edu Brian Tamanaha btamanaha at wulaw.wustl.edu Nelson Tebbe nelson.tebbe at brooklaw.edu Mark Tushnet mtushnet at law.harvard.edu Adam Winkler winkler at ucla.edu Compendium of posts on Hobby Lobby and related cases The Anti-Torture Memos: Balkinization Posts on Torture, Interrogation, Detention, War Powers, and OLC The Anti-Torture Memos (arranged by topic) Recent Posts Reflections on the Supreme Court, the Senate, and Sandy Levinson
|
Friday, April 29, 2022
Reflections on the Supreme Court, the Senate, and Sandy Levinson
Guest Blogger
This post was prepared for a
roundtable on Reforming the Supreme
Court of the United States, convened as part of LevinsonFest 2022—a
year-long series gathering scholars from diverse disciplines and viewpoints to
reflect on Sandy Levinson’s influential work in constitutional law. Vicki C. Jackson[1] Professor
Levinson has been using his powerful scholarly voice for years now to call our
attention to the increasingly hard to justify mal-distribution of the Senate
and the way its democratic deficits are hard-wired into our present
constitutional architecture.[2]
This structural defect is related to the question of Supreme Court reform. For
the disjunction between popular voting and presidential electoral success,
which arises because of the mal-distribution of the Senate and its carry-forward
to the number of votes in the Electoral College, contributes to the present
unhappy situation, as does the malapportioned Senate’s role in the confirmation
process. The
U.S. stands virtually alone, among constitutional democracies with well-established
judicial review by independent courts, in providing neither for a retirement
age nor for a limited term in office for its high court justices. Had one
looked at this issue in 1921, the United States would have had company: At that
time, Australia and Canada, countries that, like the United States, were
influenced by the British tradition, provided judges with indefinite tenure
during good behavior.[3]
However, each of these countries amended their constitutions and adopted
mandatory retirement ages for their federal judges later in the 20th
century – 70 in Australia, 75 in Canada. All but one of the U.S. states now
have term limits, or a mandatory retirement age, or both, for their high court
judges.[4]
During the New Deal period, and again in the 1950s, serious proposals were made
(though not acted upon) for a constitutional amendment creating a retirement
age for federal judges. Recently, norms about Senate confirmation have broken,
increasing the risks of a confirmation process perceived as systematically
skewing the Court and diminishing its legitimacy. Average tenures of the
justices are increasing; and the haphazard nature of when vacancies occur have
resulted in such powerfully important anomalies as President Carter having no
appointments during his four-year term and President Trump (who lost the
nationwide popular vote) having 3 – one-third of the Court – during his one
four-year term. Against
this background, I suggest that the time has come to seriously take up
proposals to limit the indefinite tenures of Supreme Court justices. Fifteen
years ago I was disinclined to support proposed changes to tenure “during good
behavior,” a provision that had so well secured an independent federal
judiciary.[5] This
past year I urged the Presidential Commission on the Supreme Court of the
United States to take very seriously the benefits of some reform and to try to
seize the moment to build a consensus in favor of change towards a more
sensible system of appointment and tenure for Supreme Court Justices. The
Commission did not do so but I hope a coalition will emerge to act. The
growing effects of the Senate’s counter-majoritarian character, together with
recent breaches of political norms and conventions about Supreme Court
appointments, are deeply concerning. Although recent abuses of the confirmation
process – against the backdrop of the counter-majoritarian effects of the
Senate – provide temptations to “Court-packing.” But sheer partisan
court-packing bears high risks of further polarization, instability and
delegitimation. Less partisan efforts to spread out appointments should be
pursued, that will not dissolve the counter-majoritarian character of the Senate
but help mitigate the way our haphazard and contingent tenure system for
Supreme Court justices can magnify the counter-majoritarian effects of the
Senate and the electoral college. Elsewhere
I discuss the potential benefits of mandatory retirement ages and 18-year
single term approaches.[6]
Here I discuss an alternative approach that Congress could constitutionally
effectuate by statute and that might avoid at least some of the risks of
being viewed as a naked partisan power grab inviting further partisan power
grabs back. Smoothing
Out Appointments Though Conditional Changes in Court Size: One of the most
compelling arguments for change in Supreme Court tenure derives from the very
uneven distribution of opportunities for Presidents, elected at different times
and from different parties, to make appointments. As the Constitution has
become more oriented to the value of equal voting and equal representation over
time, the importance of having democratically legitimate inputs to the Court
has increased. Yet the current system makes vacancies depend on contingent,
random events, and has the potential (however much it is or is not used) for
sitting justices to decide which president chooses their replacement. Given
Congress’s power to change the numbers of justices on the Court, possibilities
(other than the frequently discussed 18-year staggered terms idea) could be
considered, which could be implemented by statute. Specifically, Congress could
provide for fluctuating Court membership, [7] or a
“decoupling” of appointments from vacancies,[8] by guaranteeing one, or two,
presidential appointments each four-year term, while letting the overall
numbers on the Court fluctuate. Such approaches would spread out opportunities
for appointment, albeit not as rigorously as the 18-year term limit proposal. A
modest variation, similar to Terri Peretti’s,[9] would reflect the
desirability that, in each four-year Presidential term, at least one
appointment to the Court be made.[10] In
the last 45 years, there have been four 4-year presidential terms that had no
appointments to the Court.[11]
A statute could authorize the conditional establishment of an additional seat
on the Court (up to a limited total) in order to try to allow each four-year
presidency to choose at least one justice. So, for example, it might provide
that if by year two of a four-year term no vacancy in the 9-member Court had
occurred, a tenth seat would be created to be filled by that Presidency. If the
10th seat were filled and a further vacancy occurred, say, during
the 4th year of the same presidency, the number of authorized seats
would revert to 9. If, however, no such vacancy occurred, and a new president
was elected (or the sitting president was reelected), and by year 2 of that
presidency no vacancy had occurred, an 11th seat would be authorized
to be filled. Seats could revert down to the norm of 9 if vacancies occur,
provided that the presidency at the time had had an opportunity to make one
appointment. Such a mechanism could be capped (e.g. at 11, or 13) to keep the
Court to a workable number. The
advantages of such proposals are, first, that they could be enacted by statute.
Second, they would improve on democratic inputs to the membership of the Courts
(without requiring a constitutional amendment to depart from life tenure).
Fluctuating proposals that do not allow the Court to grow too large could not
guarantee as much regularity of democratic input as the staggered 18-year
terms, but would nonetheless be an improvement over the status quo (assuming
the Senate behaved more cooperatively, a problem across proposals).[12] Responding
to Recent Abuses of the Confirmation Process? Longstanding
structural aspects of the selection and tenure process for Supreme Court
justices warrant attention now, with a view towards a long-term fix. But some
calls for reform arise more from a felt need to respond to what are seen as
abuses of the confirmation process in very recent years.[13] As
is well-known, the Senate refused even to consider President Obama’s nomination
of Merrick Garland in March 2016, shortly after the death of Justice Scalia in
February, on the ground that it was within 8 months of a presidential election
and the Senate should wait and “give the people a voice” in the selection of a
new member of the Court.[14]
However, in the Fall of 2020, when Justice Ruth Bader Ginsburg died, the Senate
rushed to confirm the President’s nominee just weeks before the presidential
election. The proffer of a quite novel reason not to consider the Garland
nomination, combined with a complete failure to apply the reasoning to a
situation in which logically it applies a fortiori, has created
widespread concern that the confirmation process was abused. Moreover, as noted
above, President Trump – who won the presidency with fewer popular votes than
his opponent and who lost the November 2020 election in both the popular and
Electoral College vote – was able to make three appointments to the Court
during his single four-year term; President Jimmy Carter, who won a decisive popular
majority in 1976, was able to make no appointments to the Court. These
results reflect the randomness of when Supreme Court vacancies arise under our
current system, and the counter-majoritarian aspects of the Senate as presently
constituted (and operating now under quite broken norms of conduct), as well as
the effects of the two-Senators per state rule on the Electoral College. The
fluctuating Court proposals described above could help mitigate the randomness
problem. Despite
frustrations of the current moment, applying changes – whether of finite terms
or age limits – to currently sitting justices would raise concerns for judicial
independence and thus for the rule of law, especially if done by statute, which
in the United States is much easier to enact than constitutional amendment. In
countries where judges learn that they are subject to relatively easy removal
on account of their jurisprudence, it is much harder to sustain judicial
independence and the rule of law. Both, as Justice Breyer has recently
emphasized, are precious and important.[15] Expanding the Court,
without removing any existing justices, might thus be less of a threat to
judicial independence and some scholars have called for such expansion.[16] But
expanding the Court simply to give one specific President the power to fill
seats, even when in response to abuses by the other party, invites those in the
other party to engage in similar action when they return to power, and thus
risks turning the Court into even more of a perceived political football. Whether
rationalizing a decision to expand the membership on the grounds of redressing
an abuse of the confirmation process would serve to contain future responses is
at best uncertain; or whether, regardless of rationale, it would elicit “tit
for tat” action further threatening the perceived independence of the court,
are political questions on which reasonable minds might disagree. Experience
elsewhere, however, raises concern about whether, once such a process gets
started, it can be contained or would spread to create conditions in which
further intrusions on the Court’s independence could result.[17] The
broader context and the democratic deficit of the Senate: While it might thus
be imprudent simply to expand the Court for the purpose of enabling a single
President to make several appointments (however much this may be a justified
response to past abuse), the broader context in which Supreme Court justices
are selected reinforces my view that change is needed. The
Senate is designedly not a population-based entity. But the degree to which its
structure creates the risk of counter-majoritarianism is substantially greater
than that in several other federal systems with which the U.S. is often
compared and the degrees of counter-majoritarianism in Congress have increased
over time. Indeed, some scholars think it possible that, given demographic
change and the composition of the Senate, it might be that no Democratic
president will be able to appoint a Supreme Court justice again in the foreseeable
future.[18] At
the founding, the greatest disproportion between the largest state and the
smallest state was about 12.65 to 1 (Virginia being the largest by population,
Delaware being the smallest).[19]
Today, according to the 2020 census, the most populous state of California had
something like 68 times the population of the least populous state, Wyoming.[20]
Moreover, at the founding Virginia was the only state with more than ten times
the population of any other state; today, by contrast, there are ten states
with populations over 10 million, and six states with populations under 1
million.[21]
Scholars writing in the 1990s found that the minimum percentage of the
population that could elect a Senate majority has been getting smaller since
the 1860s;[22]
2020 Census data suggests that today, the 26 smallest states, with 17.5% of the
population, could in theory elect a Senate majority.[23] Although the Senate need
not have any particular partisan skew, in recent decades it has skewed in a
Republican direction.[24] It
is an unstable situation for a party supported by a minority of the population
to be able to control the Senate, frequently the Presidency, and the Supreme
Court. The constitutional amending process may also be blocked by the combined
effect of the Article V voting rules and the partisan state-by-state
demographic skew. If citizens cannot look to elections, nor the courts, nor the
amending process, to achieve a federal government that is in broad terms
responsive to democratic views, what remains are methods that should trouble
all who believe in the rule of law. Thus, even if reforms will only help at the
margins, the time has come for reforming the Supreme Court so that it may bear
somewhat more of an imprint of recently elected presidents, while at the same
time preserving the judicial independence that it has achieved. Other changes
may also be needed to the ways in which the Court exercises its jurisdiction,
but it will be for the best if the Court itself re-develops modes of judicial
restraint suitable to its position in our constitutional democracy. The
kind of statutory change suggested above – for floating numbers of seats on the
Court to enable every presidential term to make a minimum number of
appointments – would be far more modest than those Sandy Levinson has argued
for in recent years. But it might hold appeal to partisans on both sides; and
some improvement, I tend to think, is better than none. I
look forward to Sandy’s reaction – for he has been such a vigorous and
influential force for serious rethinking of the U.S. Constitution. And long may
he continue to be so! Vicki C. Jackson is the Laurence
H. Tribe Professor of Constitutional Law at Harvard Law School. You can contact
her at vjackson@law.harvard.edu. [1] This short reflection is drawn
primarily from Vicki C. Jackson, Statement to Presidential Commission on the
Supreme Court of the United States (July 16, 2021). [2] See, e.g., Sanford Levinson, Our Undemocratic Constitution
49-62 (2006). [3] Const. Act 1867 § 99(1) (Canada)
(superior court judges to hold “Office during good Behaviour,” removable only
“on Address of the Senate and House of Commons”); Austr. Const. § 72 (Australia
1901) (judges removable only on “address” from both houses of the parliament in
the same session and only for “proved misbehavior or incapacity”). Canada
amended its constitution in 1960 to provide for mandatory retirement for all
superior court judges at age 75, Const. Act 1960, 9 Eliz. II, c.2 (U.K.), an
age that had by statute applied to Supreme Court Justices since 1927; under the
1982 Constitution Act, the structure and independence of the Supreme Court are
protected. See Reference re Supreme Court Act, ss 5, 6, [2014] 1 SCR 433
(Can.). Australia amended its constitution in 1977 to require that its High
Court justices retire by age 70. Austrl. Const. § 72, ¶ 2, amended in
Constitution Alteration (Retirement of Judges), 1977 (Austrl.). [4] As of 2014, the one exception is
Rhode Island. See https://ballotpedia.org/Judicial_selection_in_Rhode_Island (citing an American Judicature
Society publication of 2014). [5] See Vicki C. Jackson, Packages
of Independence: The Selection and Tenure of Article III Judges, 95 Geo L.
J. 965, 1007-08 (2007) (suggesting that any changes life tenure could be
detrimental to the overall system of adjudication in the United States given
the dependence of many state court systems on popular elections of judges and
thus urging “great caution” before departing from existing structures securing
judicial independence). [6] See Jackson, supra note
1. [7] See especially Terri L.
Peretti, Promoting Equity in the Distribution of Supreme Court Appointments,
in Reforming the Court: Term Limits for Supreme Court Justices
435 (Roger C. Cramton & Paul Carrington eds., 2006) (guaranteeing one seat
to be filled and limiting each presidential term to filling two seats); see
also Philip D. Oliver, Increasing the Size of the Court as a Partial but
Clearly Constitutional Alternative, in id. at 405 (guaranteeing two
seats to be filled each presidential term). My proposal bears some resemblance
to theirs; they both envision a combination of a certain number of guaranteed
appointments per presidential term, coupled with a fluctuation up or down in
the number of authorized seats. Oliver’s proposal is more ambitious and might
lead to a much larger Court, which he argued was beneficial because a larger
Court would diminish a sense of entitlement to a particular seat and the
outsize (in his view) reputations of the existing nine. Oliver, at 410-11, I
worry that increasing the Court’s size by too much would make its work much
more difficult. Oliver’s suggestion that the Court could simply sit in panels, id.
at 412, while supported by some comparative experience, might require a
constitutional amendment, thereby undermining its value as a statutory
proposal. Another proposal, for a gradual increase in the Court’s membership
(to 17 or 19) -- from Jonathan Turley, Unpacking the Court, 33 Persp. on Pol. Sci. 3 (2004); see also
Jonathan Turley, Destroying the Court to Save It,
https/jonathanturley.org -- would also allow expansion beyond what I think
workable in the U.S. context and might require constitutional amendment. [8] See Daniel Hemel, Can
Structural Changes Fix the Supreme Court?, 35 J. Econ. Persp. 119, 121,
136-38 (2021) (arguing for scheme in which each President makes two
appointments at beginning of their term--but Justices do not take their seats
until after the presidential term, to diminish the “loyalty effect”). My
suggestion above is a more modest departure from current practice than Hemel’s. [9] See Peretti, supra note
7. [10] See, e.g., Steven G. Calabresi
& James Lindgren, Term Limits for the Supreme Court: Life Tenure
Reconsidered, 29 Harv. J. L & Pub
Pol’y 769, 778-81 (2006); see also Roger C. Cramton, Constitutionality
of Reforming the Supreme Court by Statute, in Reforming The Court: Term Limits For Supreme Court Justices
348 (Roger C. Cramton & Paul Carrington eds., 2006) (stating that before
1970, “almost every president serving a four-year term received at least one
appointment to the Court”). [11] See U.S. Senate, Supreme Court
Nominations (1789-present), https://www.senate.gov/legislative/nominations/SupremeCourtNominations1789present.htm (showing no Supreme Court
appointments during President Obama’s second term; President George W. Bush’s
first term; President Clinton’s second term; and President Carter’s term). [12] The 18-year term proposals assume a
reasonably cooperative Senate, a point suggesting the need to reconsider the
entire appointment process – sources of nominees, selectin mechanisms, voting
rules to select etc. [13] These concerns are reinforced by
jurisprudential trends that contribute to developments that undermine the
representative quality of our democratic institutions. See Shelby County v.
Holder, 570 U.S. 529 (2013) (invalidating Section Four of the Voting Rights
Act at a time when the Republican Party is pushing for legislation to suppress
voting); Rucho v Common Cause, 588 U.S. ___ (2019) (precluding the
possibility of federal courts addressing excessively partisan districting); Citizens
United v. FEC, 558 U.S. 310 (2010) (overruling earlier judicial decisions
and limiting legislative efforts to control the role of wealth in elections). [15] See, e.g., Stephen G. Breyer,
Scalia Lecture, The Authority of the Court and the Perils of Politics, Harvard
Law School (April 7, 2021). [16] See, e.g. Michael Klarman, Foreword:
The Degradation of American Democracy—And the Court, 134 Harv. L. Rev. 1, 250-51 (2020) (raising the possibility of Democrats
in 2021 expanding the Court by four members to “unpack” the Court in response
to Republican abuse of the confirmation process and describing “reciprocal
hardball” as “the only adequate remedy for Republican court packing”). [17] See Tom Gerald Daly, ''‘Good’
Court-Packing?,” paper presented at the Centre for Comparative Constitutional
Studies (CCCS), Melbourne Law School (8 June 2021) (discussing experience in
Argentina and Turkey); see also Joshua Braver, Court packing: An
American Tradition?, 61 B.C. L. Rev.
2747 (2020) (arguing that past changes in the size of the U.S. Court had
plausible bases (in factors like need for additional circuit judges) that were
less likely to provoke tit-for-tat responses than proposals to add multiple
seats all at once). [18] See Klarman, supra note
15, at 236 (“If sparsely populated states continue to vote mostly Republican,
then the thirty percent of Americans who pick seventy percent of the senators
would virtually guarantee Republican control [of the Senate], which would be a
legitimacy crisis of massive proportions. For example, such a Senate might
never again confirm a Democratic President's nominee to the Supreme Court.”). [19] See https://www2.census.gov/library/publications/decennial/1790/number_of_persons/1790a-02.pdf; see also Vicki C. Jackson, The
Democratic Deficit of United States Federalism: Red State, Blue State, Purple?,
46 Fed. L. Rev. 645, 650 n. 20
(2018). This proportion assumes that all persons count. IF one compares the
state populations based on the 1790 Census numbers of “free white men” over age
16 (populations of 110,936 to 11,783), the ratio was under 10:1. With special
thanks to Jonathan Gould for the references and information in this and the
next two footnotes. [20] See https://www2.census.gov/programs-surveys/decennial/2020/data/apportionment/apportionment-2020-table01.pdf. [21] See sources cited supra notes 18 and
19. [22] See Frances E. Lee & Bruce I. Oppenheimer, Sizing Up the Senate The
Unequal Consequences of Equal Representation 11 (1999); see also
Jackson, Democratic Deficit, supra note 18, at 650
(arguing that the composition of the Senate created a democratic deficit; based
on 2016 Census Bureau projections, “the 52 Republican Senators sitting in early
2017 could be said to represent states including roughly 144 million Americans,
while the 48 Democratic-caucusing Senators could, on the same basis, be said to
represent a substantial majority of about 178 million”). [23] See U.S. Census Bureau, Table
2. Resident Population for the 50 States, The District of Columbia, and Puerto
Rico: 2020 Census (2021), https://www2.census.gov/programs-surveys/decennial/2020/data/apportionment/apportionment-2020-table02.pdf. With thanks to Sam Weinstock for his
help on this note. [24] See Lee Drutman, The Senate
Has Always Favored Smaller States,. It just Didn’t Help Republicans Until Now,
Five-Thirty Eight (July 29, 2020), https://fivethirtyeight.com/features/the-senate-has-always-favored-smaller-states-it-just-didnt-help-republicans-until-now/ (explaining how over recent decades
of demographic and political change it has come to be the case – and may be the
case in the future -- that “Republicans now hold a majority of Senate seats
while only representing a minority of Americans”); see also supra note
21.
|
Books by Balkinization Bloggers Linda C. McClain and Aziza Ahmed, The Routledge Companion to Gender and COVID-19 (Routledge, 2024) David Pozen, The Constitution of the War on Drugs (Oxford University Press, 2024) Jack M. Balkin, Memory and Authority: The Uses of History in Constitutional Interpretation (Yale University Press, 2024) Mark A. Graber, Punish Treason, Reward Loyalty: The Forgotten Goals of Constitutional Reform after the Civil War (University of Kansas Press, 2023) Jack M. Balkin, What Roe v. Wade Should Have Said: The Nation's Top Legal Experts Rewrite America's Most Controversial Decision - Revised Edition (NYU Press, 2023) Andrew Koppelman, Burning Down the House: How Libertarian Philosophy Was Corrupted by Delusion and Greed (St. Martin’s Press, 2022) Gerard N. Magliocca, Washington's Heir: The Life of Justice Bushrod Washington (Oxford University Press, 2022) Joseph Fishkin and William E. Forbath, The Anti-Oligarchy Constitution: Reconstructing the Economic Foundations of American Democracy (Harvard University Press, 2022) Mark Tushnet and Bojan Bugaric, Power to the People: Constitutionalism in the Age of Populism (Oxford University Press 2021). Mark Philip Bradley and Mary L. Dudziak, eds., Making the Forever War: Marilyn B. Young on the Culture and Politics of American Militarism Culture and Politics in the Cold War and Beyond (University of Massachusetts Press, 2021). Jack M. Balkin, What Obergefell v. Hodges Should Have Said: The Nation's Top Legal Experts Rewrite America's Same-Sex Marriage Decision (Yale University Press, 2020) Frank Pasquale, New Laws of Robotics: Defending Human Expertise in the Age of AI (Belknap Press, 2020) Jack M. Balkin, The Cycles of Constitutional Time (Oxford University Press, 2020) Mark Tushnet, Taking Back the Constitution: Activist Judges and the Next Age of American Law (Yale University Press 2020). Andrew Koppelman, Gay Rights vs. Religious Liberty?: The Unnecessary Conflict (Oxford University Press, 2020) Ezekiel J Emanuel and Abbe R. Gluck, The Trillion Dollar Revolution: How the Affordable Care Act Transformed Politics, Law, and Health Care in America (PublicAffairs, 2020) Linda C. McClain, Who's the Bigot?: Learning from Conflicts over Marriage and Civil Rights Law (Oxford University Press, 2020) Sanford Levinson and Jack M. Balkin, Democracy and Dysfunction (University of Chicago Press, 2019) Sanford Levinson, Written in Stone: Public Monuments in Changing Societies (Duke University Press 2018) Mark A. Graber, Sanford Levinson, and Mark Tushnet, eds., Constitutional Democracy in Crisis? (Oxford University Press 2018) Gerard Magliocca, The Heart of the Constitution: How the Bill of Rights became the Bill of Rights (Oxford University Press, 2018) Cynthia Levinson and Sanford Levinson, Fault Lines in the Constitution: The Framers, Their Fights, and the Flaws that Affect Us Today (Peachtree Publishers, 2017) Brian Z. Tamanaha, A Realistic Theory of Law (Cambridge University Press 2017) Sanford Levinson, Nullification and Secession in Modern Constitutional Thought (University Press of Kansas 2016) Sanford Levinson, An Argument Open to All: Reading The Federalist in the 21st Century (Yale University Press 2015) Stephen M. Griffin, Broken Trust: Dysfunctional Government and Constitutional Reform (University Press of Kansas, 2015) Frank Pasquale, The Black Box Society: The Secret Algorithms That Control Money and Information (Harvard University Press, 2015) Bruce Ackerman, We the People, Volume 3: The Civil Rights Revolution (Harvard University Press, 2014) Balkinization Symposium on We the People, Volume 3: The Civil Rights Revolution Joseph Fishkin, Bottlenecks: A New Theory of Equal Opportunity (Oxford University Press, 2014) Mark A. Graber, A New Introduction to American Constitutionalism (Oxford University Press, 2013) John Mikhail, Elements of Moral Cognition: Rawls' Linguistic Analogy and the Cognitive Science of Moral and Legal Judgment (Cambridge University Press, 2013) Gerard N. Magliocca, American Founding Son: John Bingham and the Invention of the Fourteenth Amendment (New York University Press, 2013) Stephen M. Griffin, Long Wars and the Constitution (Harvard University Press, 2013) Andrew Koppelman, The Tough Luck Constitution and the Assault on Health Care Reform (Oxford University Press, 2013) James E. Fleming and Linda C. McClain, Ordered Liberty: Rights, Responsibilities, and Virtues (Harvard University Press, 2013) Balkinization Symposium on Ordered Liberty: Rights, Responsibilities, and Virtues Andrew Koppelman, Defending American Religious Neutrality (Harvard University Press, 2013) Brian Z. Tamanaha, Failing Law Schools (University of Chicago Press, 2012) Sanford Levinson, Framed: America's 51 Constitutions and the Crisis of Governance (Oxford University Press, 2012) Linda C. McClain and Joanna L. Grossman, Gender Equality: Dimensions of Women's Equal Citizenship (Cambridge University Press, 2012) Mary Dudziak, War Time: An Idea, Its History, Its Consequences (Oxford University Press, 2012) Jack M. Balkin, Living Originalism (Harvard University Press, 2011) Jason Mazzone, Copyfraud and Other Abuses of Intellectual Property Law (Stanford University Press, 2011) Richard W. Garnett and Andrew Koppelman, First Amendment Stories, (Foundation Press 2011) Jack M. Balkin, Constitutional Redemption: Political Faith in an Unjust World (Harvard University Press, 2011) Gerard Magliocca, The Tragedy of William Jennings Bryan: Constitutional Law and the Politics of Backlash (Yale University Press, 2011) Bernard Harcourt, The Illusion of Free Markets: Punishment and the Myth of Natural Order (Harvard University Press, 2010) Bruce Ackerman, The Decline and Fall of the American Republic (Harvard University Press, 2010) Balkinization Symposium on The Decline and Fall of the American Republic Ian Ayres. Carrots and Sticks: Unlock the Power of Incentives to Get Things Done (Bantam Books, 2010) Mark Tushnet, Why the Constitution Matters (Yale University Press 2010) Ian Ayres and Barry Nalebuff: Lifecycle Investing: A New, Safe, and Audacious Way to Improve the Performance of Your Retirement Portfolio (Basic Books, 2010) Jack M. Balkin, The Laws of Change: I Ching and the Philosophy of Life (2d Edition, Sybil Creek Press 2009) Brian Z. Tamanaha, Beyond the Formalist-Realist Divide: The Role of Politics in Judging (Princeton University Press 2009) Andrew Koppelman and Tobias Barrington Wolff, A Right to Discriminate?: How the Case of Boy Scouts of America v. James Dale Warped the Law of Free Association (Yale University Press 2009) Jack M. Balkin and Reva B. Siegel, The Constitution in 2020 (Oxford University Press 2009) Heather K. Gerken, The Democracy Index: Why Our Election System Is Failing and How to Fix It (Princeton University Press 2009) Mary Dudziak, Exporting American Dreams: Thurgood Marshall's African Journey (Oxford University Press 2008) David Luban, Legal Ethics and Human Dignity (Cambridge Univ. Press 2007) Ian Ayres, Super Crunchers: Why Thinking-By-Numbers is the New Way to be Smart (Bantam 2007) Jack M. Balkin, James Grimmelmann, Eddan Katz, Nimrod Kozlovski, Shlomit Wagman and Tal Zarsky, eds., Cybercrime: Digital Cops in a Networked Environment (N.Y.U. Press 2007) Jack M. Balkin and Beth Simone Noveck, The State of Play: Law, Games, and Virtual Worlds (N.Y.U. Press 2006) Andrew Koppelman, Same Sex, Different States: When Same-Sex Marriages Cross State Lines (Yale University Press 2006) Brian Tamanaha, Law as a Means to an End (Cambridge University Press 2006) Sanford Levinson, Our Undemocratic Constitution (Oxford University Press 2006) Mark Graber, Dred Scott and the Problem of Constitutional Evil (Cambridge University Press 2006) Jack M. Balkin, ed., What Roe v. Wade Should Have Said (N.Y.U. Press 2005) Sanford Levinson, ed., Torture: A Collection (Oxford University Press 2004) Balkin.com homepage Bibliography Conlaw.net Cultural Software Writings Opeds The Information Society Project BrownvBoard.com Useful Links Syllabi and Exams |