E-mail:
Jack Balkin: jackbalkin at yahoo.com
Bruce Ackerman bruce.ackerman at yale.edu
Ian Ayres ian.ayres at yale.edu
Corey Brettschneider corey_brettschneider at brown.edu
Mary Dudziak mary.l.dudziak at emory.edu
Joey Fishkin joey.fishkin at gmail.com
Heather Gerken heather.gerken at yale.edu
Abbe Gluck abbe.gluck at yale.edu
Mark Graber mgraber at law.umaryland.edu
Stephen Griffin sgriffin at tulane.edu
Jonathan Hafetz jonathan.hafetz at shu.edu
Jeremy Kessler jkessler at law.columbia.edu
Andrew Koppelman akoppelman at law.northwestern.edu
Marty Lederman msl46 at law.georgetown.edu
Sanford Levinson slevinson at law.utexas.edu
David Luban david.luban at gmail.com
Gerard Magliocca gmaglioc at iupui.edu
Jason Mazzone mazzonej at illinois.edu
Linda McClain lmcclain at bu.edu
John Mikhail mikhail at law.georgetown.edu
Frank Pasquale pasquale.frank at gmail.com
Nate Persily npersily at gmail.com
Michael Stokes Paulsen michaelstokespaulsen at gmail.com
Deborah Pearlstein dpearlst at yu.edu
Rick Pildes rick.pildes at nyu.edu
David Pozen dpozen at law.columbia.edu
Richard Primus raprimus at umich.edu
K. Sabeel Rahmansabeel.rahman at brooklaw.edu
Alice Ristroph alice.ristroph at shu.edu
Neil Siegel siegel at law.duke.edu
David Super david.super at law.georgetown.edu
Brian Tamanaha btamanaha at wulaw.wustl.edu
Nelson Tebbe nelson.tebbe at brooklaw.edu
Mark Tushnet mtushnet at law.harvard.edu
Adam Winkler winkler at ucla.edu
Miriam Seifter David Schleicher’s In a Bad State is an illuminating
and engaging tour of past and present subnational fiscal crises. Its brilliance
lies in showing how a set of tradeoffs prefigure our past and present
difficulties and the available responses to them. Like otherdomains
of policy and life where you can only “pick 2,” subnational fiscal policy is
beset by a multi-part tension. Here, federal officials confronted with a
subnational fiscal crisis can’t have it all: They can’t simultaneously avoid
the harm that flows from recessions and austerity; the moral hazard that may
follow bailouts; and the limits on lending and investment that follow defaults.
Seeing how that trilemma has scripted history, and understanding how it can
best be managed, is the fascinating journey of 11 of the book’s 12 chapters. In one final closing chapter, the book moves in a different
direction, with an argument I’ll consider in this post. Chapter 12 argues that the
excessive state debt that exacerbates fiscal crises is a result of bad state
politics. People don’t pay attention to their state officials, who then cater
to powerful interest groups with bad fiscal incentives. In the book’s parting
sentences, Schleicher asserts: “More and better state democracy would help
state and local fiscal policy, and is something we can insist on. Ultimately,
that is the best way out of a bad state.” (p.171) This is an important, generative diagnosis. I want to explore
it by asking two questions. First: Is our collective inattention to state
institutions changing, such that Schleicher is diagnosing an already-improving problem?
Second, is he prescribing the right solution? That is, will greater attention
to state-level policymaking yield improvements in the tortuous domain of state fiscal
policy? Or would we need something more or different to get to a good state? Let’s start with the first question. Schleicher undoubtedly
identifies something real when he laments our collective disengagement from
state-level democracy. Drawing his
ownprior
work and that of others like Daniel
Hopkins, Schleicher observes that voters are ignorant of state government,
vote based on national politics, and fail to hold subnational officials
accountable for their actual decisions. The result? “[S]tate and local
politicians do not seek, and do not receive, a public mandate from ordinary
voters. They are instead responsive to narrow and unrepresentative groups of
voters and interests.” (p.170) I too have
written about how state institutions may in fact be further from the
people, not closer to them. And I co-direct the State Democracy Research Initiative,
which is premised on the idea that collective neglect of state institutions
disserves to democracy. So the inadequacy of attention to state-level
institutions is well-taken. Still, I wonder, optimistically, whether some of the
well-documented inattention to state institutions is changing. The one-two
punch of the pandemic and the 2020 election showed, dramatically, the weighty consequences
of state-level policy. The recent SCOTUS decisions in Rucho and Dobbs
have led to surging interest in state courts and constitutions, and new
scholarly analysis is emerging. Heightened awareness of problems with
policing and incarceration have brought to the fore the intricacies of police
agencies, sheriffs,
andprosecutors. These developments are not just taking place in the academy.
When two legislators were
expelled from the Tennessee legislature, a major
mobilization within Tennessee and beyond its borders energized coverage
of and organizing around state legislatures. Wisconsin’s recent,
high-profile state supreme court race featured both record-breaking spending
and high turnout, and Judge Janet Protasiewicz won
by a whopping 11-point margin—an unusual margin for the state, suggesting
that at least some state races are not just mini federal races. In New York,
organizers have changed
the norms around judicial confirmations from a rubber-stamp to a hard-look
process leading to the rejection of nominee Hector LaSalle. But that brings me to my second question. Will this new energy
at the state level help improve fiscal policy? Maybe not, for two different
reasons. One is that the realm of state budgets is especially opaque.
The budgeting processes are byzantine and not well-known to the public (which
is not to say the information isn’t out there – please enjoy this 70-page
summary of Wisconsin’s process). The actual allocation and expenditure of
funds is often its own subterranean world, with peculiar norms and
institutional powers (here’s an
example from Wisconsin again, where a “secretive
pocket veto” from a legislative committee can halt spending on projects). The complexity and opacity of state fiscal policy thus seems
like one obstacle to Schleicher’s premise of more public-minded pressure on
policymakers. Fiscal stewards can’t just freeride on broad-based interest in
state policy or state courts. The world of debt and budgets has additional
levels of invisibility to surmount. There’s also the possibility of a deeper problem with
Schleicher’s democracy cure. His take, recall, is that more democracy will lead
us to better fiscal discipline. But if people knew more about state budgets, would
they actually vote and lobby in a way that would be good for rainy day funds
and manageable debt? Is majoritarian democracy good for fiscal policy? Scholars in other fields have explored this question. For
example, take the taxation that might be necessary for infrastructure or other
public services. One view is that voters generally don’t like taxes, or resist
them when the taxes are highly
visible. That makes Schleicher’s view seem dicey, because responsive
politicians may be disincentivized from raising necessary revenue. But voters also
register support for various public programs and services, and are (sometimes) willing to pay taxes to support them.
So the answer may be that it depends. The challenge of harnessing local
democracy to serve sound fiscal policy will often be a problem of design. According
to social scientists, whether voters support various tax policies seems to
hinge on framing
and phrasing,
on available information, on social movements and popular mobilization, and
even on the timing
of proposals vis-à-vis other policy steps. All of this suggests that even as more attention pours into
states, there’s no easy fix for fiscal stress. More general attention won’t
necessarily spotlight fiscal decisionmaking, and more attention to fiscal
decisionmaking won’t necessarily yield prudent decisions without careful
attention to design. But In a Bad State certainly didn’t promise easy
fixes, and Schleicher’s plea for better state democracy is welcome. To get to a
good state, we’ll need to invest carefully in state-level democracy. Miriam Seifter is a Professor of Law and faculty co-director
of the State Democracy Research Initiative at the University of Wisconsin Law
School. You can reach her by e-mail at miriam.seifter@wisc.edu.