Balkinization   |
Balkinization
Balkinization Symposiums: A Continuing List                                                                E-mail: Jack Balkin: jackbalkin at yahoo.com Bruce Ackerman bruce.ackerman at yale.edu Ian Ayres ian.ayres at yale.edu Corey Brettschneider corey_brettschneider at brown.edu Mary Dudziak mary.l.dudziak at emory.edu Joey Fishkin joey.fishkin at gmail.com Heather Gerken heather.gerken at yale.edu Abbe Gluck abbe.gluck at yale.edu Mark Graber mgraber at law.umaryland.edu Stephen Griffin sgriffin at tulane.edu Jonathan Hafetz jonathan.hafetz at shu.edu Jeremy Kessler jkessler at law.columbia.edu Andrew Koppelman akoppelman at law.northwestern.edu Marty Lederman msl46 at law.georgetown.edu Sanford Levinson slevinson at law.utexas.edu David Luban david.luban at gmail.com Gerard Magliocca gmaglioc at iupui.edu Jason Mazzone mazzonej at illinois.edu Linda McClain lmcclain at bu.edu John Mikhail mikhail at law.georgetown.edu Frank Pasquale pasquale.frank at gmail.com Nate Persily npersily at gmail.com Michael Stokes Paulsen michaelstokespaulsen at gmail.com Deborah Pearlstein dpearlst at yu.edu Rick Pildes rick.pildes at nyu.edu David Pozen dpozen at law.columbia.edu Richard Primus raprimus at umich.edu K. Sabeel Rahmansabeel.rahman at brooklaw.edu Alice Ristroph alice.ristroph at shu.edu Neil Siegel siegel at law.duke.edu David Super david.super at law.georgetown.edu Brian Tamanaha btamanaha at wulaw.wustl.edu Nelson Tebbe nelson.tebbe at brooklaw.edu Mark Tushnet mtushnet at law.harvard.edu Adam Winkler winkler at ucla.edu Compendium of posts on Hobby Lobby and related cases The Anti-Torture Memos: Balkinization Posts on Torture, Interrogation, Detention, War Powers, and OLC The Anti-Torture Memos (arranged by topic) Recent Posts Leaving Us In a Good State: Responses to and Appreciation for Comments on In a Bad State: Responding to State and Local Budget Crises
|
Friday, June 09, 2023
Leaving Us In a Good State: Responses to and Appreciation for Comments on In a Bad State: Responding to State and Local Budget Crises
Guest Blogger
First, I’d just like to thank everyone involved in this
symposium. Writing a book is a solitary
experience, and it is just wonderful to have so many people I admire commenting
on my work. Special thanks to my
wonderful colleague Jack Balkin for organizing it. This blog is a wonder – I’ve been a fan for
as long as it has existed -- and it’s an honor to get to have its pages devoted
to comments on my book. Second, before I go through some specific responses, I want
to note how excellent the responses are.
When writing the In
a Bad State: Responding to State and Local Budget Crises, I had to make
a number of choices about how to explain the ideas, what to include and what to
exclude -- a book like this, which is on the shorter side for an academic work,
has to make some pretty hard choices. Further,
the argument relies on some assumptions that I thought were reasonable but were
certainly assumptions. And then there
are assumptions and choices that I didn’t quite realize I was making, but when
pointed out and challenged, are clearly there. One of the great things about these responses is that they –
to a post – find the soft spots in the argument, as well as (much too kindly!)
noting the achievements of the book. I
hope that they are read alongside the book, a guide to understanding both how
the book succeeds and its limitations.
I’ll respond to each in turn, but mostly just to appreciate how smart and
well-done they all are. On to the meat…. I’m going to assume anyone digging this deep into the posts
has read both the responses and the book (or at least listened
to a podcast about it) so I’m not going to do a lot of recapping of the
claims of the book. Vince Buccola has emerged as one of the leading legal
experts on state finance (as well as being an important voice in corporate
finance). His
response is so smart. Like Vince, I
don’t want to spend too much debating the question of how pro-bond holder and
how out of step with prior law the 19th Century Supreme Court
railroad bond cases were (and indeed how out of step they were with the Court’s
understanding of non-infrastructure related municipal bond cases like Loan Association
v. Topeka). Buccola’s
work, with Alison Buccola, provides as convincing as argument – better than,
say, James Bradley Thayer’s defense of Gelpcke v. Dubuque – that they
were reasonable. I’m still not
convinced; it’s hard for me not to read cases like Gelpcke or the
extraordinary mandamus remedy cases as they traditionally have been read, as
aggressive and policy oriented opinions better understood as capturing the
policy ideas of the dominant Republican coalition than following relatively
neutral principles. But you should check out their contrary take, as it’s
really well done. Like Buccola, Clay Gillette – the dean of the field of the
municipal finance and law as well as a huge figure in local government law more
broadly – questions
whether it is reasonable to treat courts as being policymakers like
executive branch officials and legislators responding to the challenge of the
trilemma (among several other, well-made arguments). “So while I am confident
that David is correct in including courts, especially federal courts, in the
litany of players who address and resolve the trilemma, I am reluctant to
attribute much intentionality to judicial decisions, and I am less confident
that courts consider the global implications of their decisions. That
does not dilute David’s main point about the effects of judicial intervention,
but it does tell us something about the extent to which we can rely on courts
to strike the balance that David sees as the objective of federal
actors generally.” Gillette argues that while the main focus of the analysis – the
effect of federal decisions, including judicial decisions – basically works,
treating their decision-making as driven by similar forces as Presidential and
Congressional policy considerations may not make sense, as they are unlikely to
be considering the full set of policy implications, and may instead adopt
easier to deploy decision-making heuristics. I attempt to justify my approach in
the extremely exciting Appendix to Chapter 2 of the book, but Gillette is right
to question it. (He is similarly right
to note that judicial decisions on the enforceability of debt create nodes to
negotiate around). In response, I will
note that courts usually, although not always, share a worldview with the
dominant political coalition of which they are a part, and that it is often
therefore it makes sense to think of them as contributing to the elaboration of
that broadly-shared ideological view of how to respond to particular
crises. For instance, the Supreme
Court’s shift in its sovereign immunity doctrine before and after 1876 is
pretty hard to understand except as part of the broader shift in policy across
the federal government in its approach to Reconstruction (and therefore to the
debts incurred by Reconstruction era mixed race governments). And indeed sometimes we directly assign to
courts the power make policy along the trilemma, as I, following
Gillette’s work, suggest in its method for determining “service delivery
insolvency” in bankruptcy cases. But,
that said, Gillette’s alternate descriptions of how courts operate in these cases
is powerfully made. A few of the responses challenge on
one of the big assumptions in the work, that federal officials responding to a
state and local crisis have a pretty limited frame of policy options, and are
unlikely to seek massive structural changes in other policy areas. (I make this argument in a number of places,
but particularly in the introduction).
But it is totally fair to note that where this line is drawn is
questionable. After all, federalizing
Medicaid is a pretty big structural change, as are federal encouragement of
land use policy changes to permit greater mobility, and I advocate for
those. So maybe we can think of other
structural changes to make governments more resilient against future
crises. Sheila Foster, a leading voice in
both local government law and land use policy, smartly
notes that one can imagine a much broader set of policies that would create
resilience against future crises than the book suggests. Perhaps federal or state responses to fiscal
crises in big cities could encourage greater regionalization, if one of the
sources of urban fiscal crises is “municipal under-bounding” or cities not
being able to draw on the resources of suburbs.
Foster then discusses all sorts of interesting ways this could be
done. I don’t have too much to say in
response, other than to be a little jealous that I didn’t think of including
some of these in the book and to encourage people to read Foster’s post. It's really smart and well done. Foster explicitly draws on
Christopher Tyson’s work, and Tyson – who is both a great scholar and
policymaker in these areas – hits
some similar themes. He argues that
bankruptcy courts (in addition to Congress) might attempt to encourage changes
to municipal boundaries in Chapter 9 cases, particularly to address racial
disparities in who bears costs in cases like the Detroit bankruptcy. Other scholars – Michael
McConnell and Randy Picker and David Skeel
and Gillette – have argued Chapter 9 bankruptcy courts should consider
using their discretion in these cases to encourage or force pretty substantial
reforms in municipal policy, from tax increases to moving to at-large from
districted methods of electing city councilmembers. Tyson asks us to think even
more broadly and makes a really powerful case (if you’re at all interested in
Chapter 9, I recommend you check
out his article laying the case out in full.) Other responses specifically
question particular policy responses I suggest in the boook. Miriam Seifter and Dan Rodriguez, two of my
favorite scholars in this and indeed in any field, discuss the speculative
conclusion of the book, which argues that reforming state democracy is
necessary to address state fiscal problems fully. Seifter notes that both
she and I
have been beating the drum about the deep problems of state democracy for years
now, that voters simply follow federal party preference in state elections and
that state institutions, particularly legislatures, distort even those
preferences through their methods of aggregating votes. (Seifter’s series of papers on the failures
of state legislatures and the role of courts in state democracy is just
outstanding.) She notes optimistically that there has been some greater
attention to statehouses recently (I wish I could join her in her optimism, but
am skeptical this will mean much at the ballot box or in the medium term.). But
her powerful point is that maybe greater attention wouldn’t help states fiscal
problems. First, state fiscal issues
are really complicated, so public knowledge would have to get a lot – not a
little – better. Second, maybe greater
voter attention will lead politicians to be less responsible, or at least will
not necessarily make them more so. These points are well-taken. But one of the goals of reforms in this area
is not merely to shock people into short-run bursts of attention, but to
develop institutions that help voters aggregate and form their state-specific
policy preferences. Efforts to develop
state-specific party brands, or “quasi-parties,” in the form of group or
executive branch on-ballot endorsements, as Chris
Elemendorf and I argue, are designed to create entities that voters can
attach “running tallies” to in Morris Fiorina’s apt term. Local media can inform voters about budgets
more than simply directing them to budget data – as the CT Mirror’s great budget
report Keith Pfaneuf does regularly.
And it needs to be judged against the alternative. The absence of mass popular democracy doesn’t
mean the absence of any method of pluralistic influence, but in low-turnout
primary elections and backrooms intense policy-demanders have greater
influence, something that is quite bad for fiscal rectitude. But Seifter is surely right that the methods
of improving state democracy matter as much as simply bringing greater attention
to the issue. Rodriguez complements Seifter’s post
by focusing
on state institutions and how they might be redesigned to help avoid fiscal
crises. He notes the role of direct
democracy, allocations of power across the executive, legislative and judicial
branches, and state home rule provisions.
The effect of these reforms on fiscal policy are great areas for future
work. Although some attention was paid
to some these issues in the book – particularly the districted nature of
legislatures and its effect on spending and state fiscal constitutional rules
like balanced budget and debt limits – there is much, much more to say. Scholars working in this area would do well
to follow Rodriguez’s suggestions. Indeed, a
forthcoming paper I wrote with Rick Hills takes a small step in this
direction, arguing that courts applying the non-delegation doctrine to local
legislative delegations of power to mayors is both bad law and likely to lead
to worse policy outcomes, including less responsible budgeting. Strong mayors, we argue, are more
democratically responsive and less likely to be captured by strong policy
demanders than unknown city councilors. So
maybe that’s a start! Amy Monahan, our nation’s leading
scholar of the law of public pensions, asks
questions of my proposals for shoring up public employee pension funds. Monahan view of pensions shares much with
mine (which is no suprise, as my views draw on her work extensively). She generally endorses my idea of treating pensions
as debt for the purpose of state constitutional debt limits (Gillette, it
should be noted, has another critique, that debt limits may be too low or set
in ways that are not responsive to need, making the inclusion of pension
underfunding less useful – a good point!).
But Monahan notes that including pension underfunding in state debt
limits would be complicated, as it would require constitutionalizing the rules
of pension accounting, which are more technical than most provisions of even
our famously long state constitutions. I think this could be partially overcome
by delegating accounting standards to independent state officers, like state
comptrollers, or even to courts. Even if some chicanery was still allowed,
including pension underfunding in debt limits would be an improvement on the
status quo. But Monahan is right – it’s
definitely a problem. Instead, Monahan argues that we
should consider including public pensions in the ERISA system we use for
private defined benefit pensions. This is
a very promising idea, although one with some substantial difficulties of its
own, which Monahan notes. Either way,
doing something to make states treat underfunded pensions as debt,
rather than as a form of quasi-debt that does not count against balanced budget
or debt limits, would be very attractive.
Our current legal system encourages pension underfunding, and
discourages debt issuances to build things, the exact opposite of what we
should want. A final group of responses
addresses one of the biggest assumptions of the argument and choices in the
form of the book -- the decision to study the issue through the lens of
American history, searching for lessons for today from the American past,
rather than, say, emulating what the existing leading book on the subject,
Jonathan Rodden’s great book Hamilton’s
Paradox: The Promise and Peril of Fiscal Federalism did, looking at the
issue comparatively across countries. Noah Kazis is a great local
government law scholar, the future of the field, and his response is so typical
of his work – sharp, insightful, modest in tone but sweeping in its impact. His central critique of the book is that the
trilemma works less well as a heuristic in the modern era, as the relationship
between the federal government and state and local governments has gotten
deeper and more differentiated. Does it
make sense to understand the politics of infrastructure today the same way we
did in the 19th century? To talk about the state of Illinois and the
MTA using the same tools? It is surely true that changes in
time and differences the types of subnational governments means that analyzing
the merits of a response to a particular fiscal crises can’t pull directly from
historical examples. Kazis’s point here
is really powerful and profound. It is
why I argue that the trilemma provides us with the right questions to ask, but that
the weights one applies in any given instance will depend mightly on all sorts
of specific factors. Whether an
intervention will create a lot or a little austerity, moral hazard or harm to
the municipal bond market will depend on differences case-to-case. Kazis is right to note that general
theoretical approaches to questions of federalism will often not be powerful
enough to help us in specific cases. But the trilemma has things to tell
us these cases nonetheless. To take one
of Kazis’s examples, a fiscal crisis in a transit agency like New York’s Metropolitan
Transit Authority (MTA) that gets a very substantial part of its revenue from
the federal government would certainly pose different questions from a default
in a 19th century U.S. state.
But the federal government – and in particular the Federal Reserve --
still had to face the question of whether to extend its Municipal Liquidity
Facility to special districts, which everyone knew meant making it available to
the MTA (the MTA ended up being one of two entities to borrow from the MLF). How should it have thought of this problem? The
federal government surely had lots of tools for addressing the financial
problems of transit agencies, and ended up giving them lots in direct aid. But using an administrative like the MLF
provided real benefits, as it helped target federal aid at a time when most
fiscal aid to states, cities and districts was untargeted due to the
difficulties of passing specific aid packages in a Congress with
districts. But doing so raised real
questions of moral hazard, so the MLF required a high interest rate. Other choices – default or austerity –were
available and considered, but were understood under the conditions of COVID to
be too costly. The debate over what the
MLF should do was very intense, but few voices – at least outside of the Fed
itself – seemed to see the trade-offs involved.
Was the Fed’s decision informed by the particularities of the need for
transit in an era of global warming, the influence of particular Senators, and the
cost of default amid a broader financial panic? Of course, but the specifics of
responses to, say, the Post-Reconstruction era defaults or the railroad bond
cases had their own specific problems as well.
Kazis’s powerful argument is that history can only provide so much of a
guide to policy making. That’s right,
but it also can help us see things we might otherwise miss. One last note
on Kazis’s excellent post, he questions whether the story I tell for why states
and cities build most infrastructure is right.
I argue – following Barry Weingast and John Ferejohn – that the
districted nature of Congress and the informational difficulties of planning
from Washington have meant that federal efforts to build infrastructure are
doomed for failure, to being spread across too many districts due to
“distributive politics.” As a result,
states and cities are left responsible for most infrastructure and always have
been. Kazis notes that I don’t really
spend too much defending this argument. Further, as a normative argument, it is
built on some shaky foundation – are the informational problems as bad today as
they were in the past? Aren’t the problems of pork-barrel spending even worse
at the state and local level? These are very
good points! The book doesn’t attempt to normatively justify the federal
government’s failure to build infrastructure, but does assume that it is a
constant, for the reasons Ferejohn and Weingast lay out. Perhaps it could
change? I doubt it – I think these forces have a lot more explanatory and
normative force than Kazis suggests. But
should it? It’s certainly something that should be on the table. But it’s also
right that the book doesn’t lay out a full throated argument in defense of that
position. It offers a less than
full-throated one, but it’s a short book.
So I 100% agree that, like most authors of books of this sort, I faced
some difficult tradeoffs. Kazis writes: “He could 1)
write usefully for a broad and policy-oriented audience; 2) pull in all the
issues he has shown local debt and distress to be connected with (from
sovereign immunity to land use reform and the creation of a VAT system); and 3)
cover them across disparate institutional contexts and eras of history.” I
tried, following an argument in the book, for balance, to fail at each of these
a little bit, rather than to fail at one dramatically. Whether I succeed is for you to decide. But abstracted away from the context of this
project, figuring out where on this trilemma – the Kazis book trilemma? – one
wants to land should be something any author of a book should consider. Finally, the
legendary Rick Hills questions the other major choice, the domestic focus of the book. He offers a bravura analysis applying some of
the lessons of the book to the biggest problem in local governmental debt in
the world – the debt crisis in Chinese local governments. The book’s domestic focus helps us see things
like the connection between Congress’s districted nature and state debt. But it limits its scope. I can’t assess
Hills’s argument, except that it sure seems compelling! I want to learn from
it. Also, despite having written nearly
a dozen articles together (and more to come!), I’m still amazed Rick’s
work. Who else would have written
sentences like these?
|
Books by Balkinization Bloggers Linda C. McClain and Aziza Ahmed, The Routledge Companion to Gender and COVID-19 (Routledge, 2024) David Pozen, The Constitution of the War on Drugs (Oxford University Press, 2024) Jack M. Balkin, Memory and Authority: The Uses of History in Constitutional Interpretation (Yale University Press, 2024) Mark A. Graber, Punish Treason, Reward Loyalty: The Forgotten Goals of Constitutional Reform after the Civil War (University of Kansas Press, 2023) Jack M. Balkin, What Roe v. Wade Should Have Said: The Nation's Top Legal Experts Rewrite America's Most Controversial Decision - Revised Edition (NYU Press, 2023) Andrew Koppelman, Burning Down the House: How Libertarian Philosophy Was Corrupted by Delusion and Greed (St. Martin’s Press, 2022) Gerard N. Magliocca, Washington's Heir: The Life of Justice Bushrod Washington (Oxford University Press, 2022) Joseph Fishkin and William E. Forbath, The Anti-Oligarchy Constitution: Reconstructing the Economic Foundations of American Democracy (Harvard University Press, 2022) Mark Tushnet and Bojan Bugaric, Power to the People: Constitutionalism in the Age of Populism (Oxford University Press 2021). Mark Philip Bradley and Mary L. Dudziak, eds., Making the Forever War: Marilyn B. Young on the Culture and Politics of American Militarism Culture and Politics in the Cold War and Beyond (University of Massachusetts Press, 2021). Jack M. Balkin, What Obergefell v. Hodges Should Have Said: The Nation's Top Legal Experts Rewrite America's Same-Sex Marriage Decision (Yale University Press, 2020) Frank Pasquale, New Laws of Robotics: Defending Human Expertise in the Age of AI (Belknap Press, 2020) Jack M. Balkin, The Cycles of Constitutional Time (Oxford University Press, 2020) Mark Tushnet, Taking Back the Constitution: Activist Judges and the Next Age of American Law (Yale University Press 2020). Andrew Koppelman, Gay Rights vs. Religious Liberty?: The Unnecessary Conflict (Oxford University Press, 2020) Ezekiel J Emanuel and Abbe R. Gluck, The Trillion Dollar Revolution: How the Affordable Care Act Transformed Politics, Law, and Health Care in America (PublicAffairs, 2020) Linda C. McClain, Who's the Bigot?: Learning from Conflicts over Marriage and Civil Rights Law (Oxford University Press, 2020) Sanford Levinson and Jack M. Balkin, Democracy and Dysfunction (University of Chicago Press, 2019) Sanford Levinson, Written in Stone: Public Monuments in Changing Societies (Duke University Press 2018) Mark A. Graber, Sanford Levinson, and Mark Tushnet, eds., Constitutional Democracy in Crisis? (Oxford University Press 2018) Gerard Magliocca, The Heart of the Constitution: How the Bill of Rights became the Bill of Rights (Oxford University Press, 2018) Cynthia Levinson and Sanford Levinson, Fault Lines in the Constitution: The Framers, Their Fights, and the Flaws that Affect Us Today (Peachtree Publishers, 2017) Brian Z. Tamanaha, A Realistic Theory of Law (Cambridge University Press 2017) Sanford Levinson, Nullification and Secession in Modern Constitutional Thought (University Press of Kansas 2016) Sanford Levinson, An Argument Open to All: Reading The Federalist in the 21st Century (Yale University Press 2015) Stephen M. Griffin, Broken Trust: Dysfunctional Government and Constitutional Reform (University Press of Kansas, 2015) Frank Pasquale, The Black Box Society: The Secret Algorithms That Control Money and Information (Harvard University Press, 2015) Bruce Ackerman, We the People, Volume 3: The Civil Rights Revolution (Harvard University Press, 2014) Balkinization Symposium on We the People, Volume 3: The Civil Rights Revolution Joseph Fishkin, Bottlenecks: A New Theory of Equal Opportunity (Oxford University Press, 2014) Mark A. Graber, A New Introduction to American Constitutionalism (Oxford University Press, 2013) John Mikhail, Elements of Moral Cognition: Rawls' Linguistic Analogy and the Cognitive Science of Moral and Legal Judgment (Cambridge University Press, 2013) Gerard N. Magliocca, American Founding Son: John Bingham and the Invention of the Fourteenth Amendment (New York University Press, 2013) Stephen M. Griffin, Long Wars and the Constitution (Harvard University Press, 2013) Andrew Koppelman, The Tough Luck Constitution and the Assault on Health Care Reform (Oxford University Press, 2013) James E. Fleming and Linda C. McClain, Ordered Liberty: Rights, Responsibilities, and Virtues (Harvard University Press, 2013) Balkinization Symposium on Ordered Liberty: Rights, Responsibilities, and Virtues Andrew Koppelman, Defending American Religious Neutrality (Harvard University Press, 2013) Brian Z. Tamanaha, Failing Law Schools (University of Chicago Press, 2012) Sanford Levinson, Framed: America's 51 Constitutions and the Crisis of Governance (Oxford University Press, 2012) Linda C. McClain and Joanna L. Grossman, Gender Equality: Dimensions of Women's Equal Citizenship (Cambridge University Press, 2012) Mary Dudziak, War Time: An Idea, Its History, Its Consequences (Oxford University Press, 2012) Jack M. Balkin, Living Originalism (Harvard University Press, 2011) Jason Mazzone, Copyfraud and Other Abuses of Intellectual Property Law (Stanford University Press, 2011) Richard W. Garnett and Andrew Koppelman, First Amendment Stories, (Foundation Press 2011) Jack M. Balkin, Constitutional Redemption: Political Faith in an Unjust World (Harvard University Press, 2011) Gerard Magliocca, The Tragedy of William Jennings Bryan: Constitutional Law and the Politics of Backlash (Yale University Press, 2011) Bernard Harcourt, The Illusion of Free Markets: Punishment and the Myth of Natural Order (Harvard University Press, 2010) Bruce Ackerman, The Decline and Fall of the American Republic (Harvard University Press, 2010) Balkinization Symposium on The Decline and Fall of the American Republic Ian Ayres. Carrots and Sticks: Unlock the Power of Incentives to Get Things Done (Bantam Books, 2010) Mark Tushnet, Why the Constitution Matters (Yale University Press 2010) Ian Ayres and Barry Nalebuff: Lifecycle Investing: A New, Safe, and Audacious Way to Improve the Performance of Your Retirement Portfolio (Basic Books, 2010) Jack M. Balkin, The Laws of Change: I Ching and the Philosophy of Life (2d Edition, Sybil Creek Press 2009) Brian Z. Tamanaha, Beyond the Formalist-Realist Divide: The Role of Politics in Judging (Princeton University Press 2009) Andrew Koppelman and Tobias Barrington Wolff, A Right to Discriminate?: How the Case of Boy Scouts of America v. James Dale Warped the Law of Free Association (Yale University Press 2009) Jack M. Balkin and Reva B. Siegel, The Constitution in 2020 (Oxford University Press 2009) Heather K. Gerken, The Democracy Index: Why Our Election System Is Failing and How to Fix It (Princeton University Press 2009) Mary Dudziak, Exporting American Dreams: Thurgood Marshall's African Journey (Oxford University Press 2008) David Luban, Legal Ethics and Human Dignity (Cambridge Univ. Press 2007) Ian Ayres, Super Crunchers: Why Thinking-By-Numbers is the New Way to be Smart (Bantam 2007) Jack M. Balkin, James Grimmelmann, Eddan Katz, Nimrod Kozlovski, Shlomit Wagman and Tal Zarsky, eds., Cybercrime: Digital Cops in a Networked Environment (N.Y.U. Press 2007) Jack M. Balkin and Beth Simone Noveck, The State of Play: Law, Games, and Virtual Worlds (N.Y.U. Press 2006) Andrew Koppelman, Same Sex, Different States: When Same-Sex Marriages Cross State Lines (Yale University Press 2006) Brian Tamanaha, Law as a Means to an End (Cambridge University Press 2006) Sanford Levinson, Our Undemocratic Constitution (Oxford University Press 2006) Mark Graber, Dred Scott and the Problem of Constitutional Evil (Cambridge University Press 2006) Jack M. Balkin, ed., What Roe v. Wade Should Have Said (N.Y.U. Press 2005) Sanford Levinson, ed., Torture: A Collection (Oxford University Press 2004) Balkin.com homepage Bibliography Conlaw.net Cultural Software Writings Opeds The Information Society Project BrownvBoard.com Useful Links Syllabi and Exams |