Balkinization   |
Balkinization
Balkinization Symposiums: A Continuing List                                                                E-mail: Jack Balkin: jackbalkin at yahoo.com Bruce Ackerman bruce.ackerman at yale.edu Ian Ayres ian.ayres at yale.edu Corey Brettschneider corey_brettschneider at brown.edu Mary Dudziak mary.l.dudziak at emory.edu Joey Fishkin joey.fishkin at gmail.com Heather Gerken heather.gerken at yale.edu Abbe Gluck abbe.gluck at yale.edu Mark Graber mgraber at law.umaryland.edu Stephen Griffin sgriffin at tulane.edu Jonathan Hafetz jonathan.hafetz at shu.edu Jeremy Kessler jkessler at law.columbia.edu Andrew Koppelman akoppelman at law.northwestern.edu Marty Lederman msl46 at law.georgetown.edu Sanford Levinson slevinson at law.utexas.edu David Luban david.luban at gmail.com Gerard Magliocca gmaglioc at iupui.edu Jason Mazzone mazzonej at illinois.edu Linda McClain lmcclain at bu.edu John Mikhail mikhail at law.georgetown.edu Frank Pasquale pasquale.frank at gmail.com Nate Persily npersily at gmail.com Michael Stokes Paulsen michaelstokespaulsen at gmail.com Deborah Pearlstein dpearlst at yu.edu Rick Pildes rick.pildes at nyu.edu David Pozen dpozen at law.columbia.edu Richard Primus raprimus at umich.edu K. Sabeel Rahmansabeel.rahman at brooklaw.edu Alice Ristroph alice.ristroph at shu.edu Neil Siegel siegel at law.duke.edu David Super david.super at law.georgetown.edu Brian Tamanaha btamanaha at wulaw.wustl.edu Nelson Tebbe nelson.tebbe at brooklaw.edu Mark Tushnet mtushnet at law.harvard.edu Adam Winkler winkler at ucla.edu Compendium of posts on Hobby Lobby and related cases The Anti-Torture Memos: Balkinization Posts on Torture, Interrogation, Detention, War Powers, and OLC The Anti-Torture Memos (arranged by topic) Recent Posts Can Courts Resolve the Trilemma?
|
Saturday, June 03, 2023
Can Courts Resolve the Trilemma?
Guest Blogger
For the Balkinization symposium on David Schleicher, In a Bad State: Responding to State and Local Budget Crises (Oxford University Press, 2023). Clayton P. Gillette David Schleicher’s
terrific new book, In a Bad State,
offers a novel and cohesive account of the various objectives (bailout,
austerity, measured default) that the federal government might pursue in the
face of state and local fiscal crisis, and compellingly analyzes the
impossibility of simultaneously achieving all of those goals. By providing a roadmap to the manner in which
academics and policy makers must think about actual and potential distress,
David’s insight, which amounts to an Arrow’s Theorem for fiscal crisis, stands
as a major contribution to the literature.
I want to focus on the
role of courts in addressing or resolving David’s trilemma. David treats the courts, especially the
Supreme Court, as an equal partner in structuring a federal response. I am less confident that courts play the role
that David attributes to them, in part because of the limited function of
courts and in part because of their relationship with the executive and
legislative branches. In short, I want
to suggest that while David is certainly correct in focusing on courts as major
players in confronting the trilemma, they are structurally and functionally
different from the other relevant actors.
And those differences bring into question whether courts can play a
coherent, intentional role in resolving the trilemma, or whether their
contributions only fortuitously coincide with one or more of the objectives of
other federal branches. Courts, of course,
have little capacity to bail out distressed localities because they cannot
mandate that more centralized governments provide bailout funding to distressed
decentralized units. Of course, courts
could provide a form of bailout by invalidating debt and leaving the issuer
with funds that alleviate distress, which is essentially what some courts did
in the railroad bond era. But that is
not a bailout in the sense that David is using it, that is, to provide funding
that would make creditors whole while simultaneously preserving local capacity
to fund local infrastructure and services. Courts can more easily
address the second and third lemmas.
They can avoid moral hazard by mandating debt payments and invalidating
state efforts to impair those obligations.
That is essentially what David suspects the Supreme Court did in the
late 19th century when states attempted to rescue distressed
localities, or what the New York Court of Appeals did when it struck down the
state’s Moratorium Act during New York City’s fiscal crisis in the 1970s. And courts can facilitate default and manage
loss sharing, notwithstanding the resulting effects on subsequent investment,
by upholding state schemes to compromise debt.
Examples here include the Supreme Court’s tolerance of mortgage
moratorium acts during the Depression. Or,
courts can manipulate legislatively granted bankruptcy to spread the risks
associated with a managed default. So in theory, courts
could be a significant partner in addressing and resolving the trilemma, even
if not a full partner given their inability to provide or require funding. But I wonder whether court participation in
the process counts as a deliberate intervention to achieve one or more of the
objectives of the trilemma or a more coincidental by-product of other judicial functions. When the executive or legislative branches
intervene in a fiscal crisis, whether by providing funding, refusing to provide
funding, or creating a bankruptcy alternative, they do so quite specifically,
intentionally, and presumably with an understanding of how their decisions impact
the competing interests in the trilemma.
Courts might act the same way. There have been times when courts have
revealed that they are quite cognizant of the fiscal and investment
implications of their decisions in narrow cases. The famous Charles River Bridge case, for example, was nominally about whether
an exclusive license to operate a bridge must remain in perpetuity or could be
circumvented when the government licensor found an allegedly superior
alternative. But the state and federal
judges who addressed that narrow question quite explicitly addressed the
effects of their decision on the willingness of entrepreneurs to make socially
productive investments in new technologies, such as railroads and canals. Courts, that is, are not necessarily
oblivious to the consequences of their decisions. Yet, I am hesitant to
attribute that foresightedness and rigor to the decisions that David
discusses. Perhaps when judicial
decisions advance one of the lemmas in David’s puzzle, that is simply a
necessary effect of some other function the court is attempting to pursue. After all, what was the Supreme Court trying
to accomplish when it elevated creditors’ rights over state and municipal
solvency in the late 19th century?
Were the justices and the state and federal judges who followed that
line of decisions primarily concerned with consequences for subsequent infrastructure
investment? Perhaps. But the language of the opinions was often
much loftier, as when the Court said, in Wolff
v. City of New Orleans that a legislative scheme to limit taxes that
secured outstanding bonds offended the “inviolability of contracts,” and perhaps
judges meant what they said, that they were simply engaged in enforcing
promises, indifferent to the consequences for any specific promise. Maybe, as Erik Monkkonen has argued, judges
were opposed to debtors whom courts perceived had defaulted for political
rather than fiscal reasons. Or perhaps,
as Vincent and Allison Buccola have argued, the cases tell a complicated story
in which the Supreme Court decided cases in a nuanced manner consistent with an
information cost explanation. If grounds
for bond invalidity were easily accessible to bondholders, e.g., compliance
with a requirement that residents vote for the bond issue, then bondholders
bore the validity risk. If those same
bondholders could not easily access information that confirmed validity, e.g.,
suspect bonds were issued in excess of state constitutional debt limits, then a
recital within the bonds that there had been compliance with the legal
prerequisites for issuance would estop the issuer from denying validity. That conclusion would
be consistent with a story in which courts are attempting to impose losses on
that group that is in the best position to have avoided the crisis in the first
instance. I have argued elsewhere that
creditors rather than residents of distressed municipalities often occupy that
position. Where that is the case, we
might do better to allow localities to default, thus sending a signal to
creditors to take advantage of their superior position to avoid the next
crisis. But that has little to do with
the interests recognized in the trilemma.
Or perhaps, judges who invalidated bonds simply shared Judge Dillon’s
animosity towards public funds being used for redistributive purposes,
including subsidizing private enterprise, regardless of potential positive
effects for local economies. Finally, courts might
simply be somewhat woodenly following their view of what the law requires of
them, consequences be damned. In some
sense, of course, that is exactly what we expect of courts, at least where
legislatures have been sufficiently directive in making political
decisions. David recounts an explicit
example of this in Central Falls, Rhode Island, where the legislature, at the
behest of bondholders, enacted a statute that gave bondholders a first lien on
the property taxes that secured their bonds, thus preventing pensioners and
residents of reaching those revenues during the city’s bankruptcy. Bond counsel have recommended such first lien
statutes broadly and many jurisdictions have adopted them. Unless a court were to hold that such a lien
did not constitute the kind of statutory lien that deserves protection in bankruptcy,
those statutes sorely constrain courts in choosing which lemma to pursue. So while I am
confident that David is correct in including courts, especially federal courts,
in the litany of players who address and resolve the trilemma, I am reluctant
to attribute much intentionality to judicial decisions, and I am less confident
that courts consider the global implications of their decisions. That does not dilute David’s main point about
the effects of judicial intervention, but it does tell us something about the
extent to which we can rely on courts to strike the balance that David sees as
the objective of federal actors
generally. But there is one additional role that courts play that
I believe is worth considering. Courts
create entitlements around which debtors and creditors can bargain. When courts address disputes about the
validity of debt, they frequently are doing more than allocating losses in a
zero-sum game about whether debts will be paid or not. Instead, debtors and creditors have
traditionally sought judicial resolution after a state has intervened to assist
a distressed political subdivision in a manner that disadvantages creditors. This was the case with the 19th
century state acts to reallocate assets initially pledged by distressed
localities and with 20th century moratorium acts. But a careful reading the relevant cases
reveals that states did not simply intervene to divert municipal assets from
creditors. Rather, those legislative interventions
tended to occur after debtors and creditors had entered into ultimately
unsuccessful negotiations about partial payments that would spread the loss of
financial distress in the way that David suggests may be appropriate. Without a bankruptcy law to compromise debts,
creditors could hold out for substantial payments regardless of consequences
for debtor services. States responded by
giving debtors an advantage, sometime by dissolving the indebted municipality.
But the states that did so frequently recognized that their decisions were
contingent on subsequent negotiations with creditors, sometimes going so far as
to include a reservation price for adjusting the debt. In effect, the states attempted to assign an
entitlement, one of nonpayment, that would give debtor municipalities an
advantage over holdout creditors in subsequent Coasean bargaining. Courts that invalidated the state schemes
were essentially reversing that entitlement, assigning it instead to creditors
who would then have an advantage in the subsequent negotiations. Perhaps the most blatant example of courts playing the
role of establishing a default rule and allowing bargaining to allocate losses occurred
in New York when the Court of Appeals invalidated the state’s Moratorium
Act. One would have thought that the
upshot of that decision was that New York City had to pay its debts immediately
without reservation. But here’s what the
court said after holding that the moratorium on NYC note payments was
unconstitutional: “In order to minimize market and governmental disruptions
which might ensue it would be injudicious at this time to allow the
extraordinary remedies in the nature of injunction and peremptory mandamus
sought by plaintiff. Plaintiff and other noteholders of the city are entitled
to some judicial relief free of throttling by the moratorium statute, but they
are not entitled immediately to extraordinary or any particular judicial
measures unnecessarily disruptive of the city's delicate financial and economic
balance. It is significant too that the Legislature will shortly meet in
regular annual session and will be in a position once again to treat with the
city's problems and to seek a fiscal solution in the light of the holding in
this case. It would serve neither plaintiff nor the people of the City of New
York precipitately to invoke instant judicial remedies which might give the
city no choice except to proceed into bankruptcy.” Fostering loss-sharing negotiations around a
default rule may be the most useful role that a court can play in resolving the
trilemma. I have one last
thought about the ambiguous judicial role in this area. As David so thoroughly demonstrates, the
trigger for many crises in our history involves debt limits that state
constitutions impose on states and their political subdivisions. These debt limits not only constrain states
and localities in their efforts to construct necessary infrastructure, but also
force those entities into expensive, if creative, efforts to circumvent debt
limits with multiple authorities, sale and leasebacks, revenue bonds that have
no special revenue, and other mechanisms that obfuscate the debt position of
states and localities. Similarly, debt
limits induce courts to undertake mental gymnastics to define what obligations
are within and without the limits so that, as David indicates, general
obligations count, but pension obligations to be paid out of the same revenues
do not. David correctly suggests that
debt limit need reform. That might be
useful if debt limits were set to some ideal measure of affordability. But debt limits vary so much in their
baseline and their calculation that they belie any claim that they are related
to ideal affordability. Perhaps if, as
David and others have suggested, we demanded more transparency in the debt
position of states and localities and avoided the artificial debt limits, we
would increase monitoring by residents and markets that would allow pricing and
political accountability to signal impending fiscal crisis. That might be a consequence of eliminating
debt limits and the subsequent need for peculiar judicial constructions of
their scope. I’m not sure of that. After all, resident monitoring suffers from a
classic collective action problem, and institutional investors may be more
likely to handle risk through diversified portfolios than by costly monitoring
of individual issuers. But to the extent
that artificial debt limits contribute to, rather than avoid fiscal crisis, it
may be time to rethink their antiquarian status and utility. Clayton Gillette (clayton.gillette@nyu.edu) is the Max
E. Greenberg Professor of Contract Law at NYU School of Law.
|
Books by Balkinization Bloggers Linda C. McClain and Aziza Ahmed, The Routledge Companion to Gender and COVID-19 (Routledge, 2024) David Pozen, The Constitution of the War on Drugs (Oxford University Press, 2024) Jack M. Balkin, Memory and Authority: The Uses of History in Constitutional Interpretation (Yale University Press, 2024) Mark A. Graber, Punish Treason, Reward Loyalty: The Forgotten Goals of Constitutional Reform after the Civil War (University of Kansas Press, 2023) Jack M. Balkin, What Roe v. Wade Should Have Said: The Nation's Top Legal Experts Rewrite America's Most Controversial Decision - Revised Edition (NYU Press, 2023) Andrew Koppelman, Burning Down the House: How Libertarian Philosophy Was Corrupted by Delusion and Greed (St. Martin’s Press, 2022) Gerard N. Magliocca, Washington's Heir: The Life of Justice Bushrod Washington (Oxford University Press, 2022) Joseph Fishkin and William E. Forbath, The Anti-Oligarchy Constitution: Reconstructing the Economic Foundations of American Democracy (Harvard University Press, 2022) Mark Tushnet and Bojan Bugaric, Power to the People: Constitutionalism in the Age of Populism (Oxford University Press 2021). Mark Philip Bradley and Mary L. Dudziak, eds., Making the Forever War: Marilyn B. Young on the Culture and Politics of American Militarism Culture and Politics in the Cold War and Beyond (University of Massachusetts Press, 2021). Jack M. Balkin, What Obergefell v. Hodges Should Have Said: The Nation's Top Legal Experts Rewrite America's Same-Sex Marriage Decision (Yale University Press, 2020) Frank Pasquale, New Laws of Robotics: Defending Human Expertise in the Age of AI (Belknap Press, 2020) Jack M. Balkin, The Cycles of Constitutional Time (Oxford University Press, 2020) Mark Tushnet, Taking Back the Constitution: Activist Judges and the Next Age of American Law (Yale University Press 2020). Andrew Koppelman, Gay Rights vs. Religious Liberty?: The Unnecessary Conflict (Oxford University Press, 2020) Ezekiel J Emanuel and Abbe R. Gluck, The Trillion Dollar Revolution: How the Affordable Care Act Transformed Politics, Law, and Health Care in America (PublicAffairs, 2020) Linda C. McClain, Who's the Bigot?: Learning from Conflicts over Marriage and Civil Rights Law (Oxford University Press, 2020) Sanford Levinson and Jack M. Balkin, Democracy and Dysfunction (University of Chicago Press, 2019) Sanford Levinson, Written in Stone: Public Monuments in Changing Societies (Duke University Press 2018) Mark A. Graber, Sanford Levinson, and Mark Tushnet, eds., Constitutional Democracy in Crisis? (Oxford University Press 2018) Gerard Magliocca, The Heart of the Constitution: How the Bill of Rights became the Bill of Rights (Oxford University Press, 2018) Cynthia Levinson and Sanford Levinson, Fault Lines in the Constitution: The Framers, Their Fights, and the Flaws that Affect Us Today (Peachtree Publishers, 2017) Brian Z. Tamanaha, A Realistic Theory of Law (Cambridge University Press 2017) Sanford Levinson, Nullification and Secession in Modern Constitutional Thought (University Press of Kansas 2016) Sanford Levinson, An Argument Open to All: Reading The Federalist in the 21st Century (Yale University Press 2015) Stephen M. Griffin, Broken Trust: Dysfunctional Government and Constitutional Reform (University Press of Kansas, 2015) Frank Pasquale, The Black Box Society: The Secret Algorithms That Control Money and Information (Harvard University Press, 2015) Bruce Ackerman, We the People, Volume 3: The Civil Rights Revolution (Harvard University Press, 2014) Balkinization Symposium on We the People, Volume 3: The Civil Rights Revolution Joseph Fishkin, Bottlenecks: A New Theory of Equal Opportunity (Oxford University Press, 2014) Mark A. Graber, A New Introduction to American Constitutionalism (Oxford University Press, 2013) John Mikhail, Elements of Moral Cognition: Rawls' Linguistic Analogy and the Cognitive Science of Moral and Legal Judgment (Cambridge University Press, 2013) Gerard N. Magliocca, American Founding Son: John Bingham and the Invention of the Fourteenth Amendment (New York University Press, 2013) Stephen M. Griffin, Long Wars and the Constitution (Harvard University Press, 2013) Andrew Koppelman, The Tough Luck Constitution and the Assault on Health Care Reform (Oxford University Press, 2013) James E. Fleming and Linda C. McClain, Ordered Liberty: Rights, Responsibilities, and Virtues (Harvard University Press, 2013) Balkinization Symposium on Ordered Liberty: Rights, Responsibilities, and Virtues Andrew Koppelman, Defending American Religious Neutrality (Harvard University Press, 2013) Brian Z. Tamanaha, Failing Law Schools (University of Chicago Press, 2012) Sanford Levinson, Framed: America's 51 Constitutions and the Crisis of Governance (Oxford University Press, 2012) Linda C. McClain and Joanna L. Grossman, Gender Equality: Dimensions of Women's Equal Citizenship (Cambridge University Press, 2012) Mary Dudziak, War Time: An Idea, Its History, Its Consequences (Oxford University Press, 2012) Jack M. Balkin, Living Originalism (Harvard University Press, 2011) Jason Mazzone, Copyfraud and Other Abuses of Intellectual Property Law (Stanford University Press, 2011) Richard W. Garnett and Andrew Koppelman, First Amendment Stories, (Foundation Press 2011) Jack M. Balkin, Constitutional Redemption: Political Faith in an Unjust World (Harvard University Press, 2011) Gerard Magliocca, The Tragedy of William Jennings Bryan: Constitutional Law and the Politics of Backlash (Yale University Press, 2011) Bernard Harcourt, The Illusion of Free Markets: Punishment and the Myth of Natural Order (Harvard University Press, 2010) Bruce Ackerman, The Decline and Fall of the American Republic (Harvard University Press, 2010) Balkinization Symposium on The Decline and Fall of the American Republic Ian Ayres. Carrots and Sticks: Unlock the Power of Incentives to Get Things Done (Bantam Books, 2010) Mark Tushnet, Why the Constitution Matters (Yale University Press 2010) Ian Ayres and Barry Nalebuff: Lifecycle Investing: A New, Safe, and Audacious Way to Improve the Performance of Your Retirement Portfolio (Basic Books, 2010) Jack M. Balkin, The Laws of Change: I Ching and the Philosophy of Life (2d Edition, Sybil Creek Press 2009) Brian Z. Tamanaha, Beyond the Formalist-Realist Divide: The Role of Politics in Judging (Princeton University Press 2009) Andrew Koppelman and Tobias Barrington Wolff, A Right to Discriminate?: How the Case of Boy Scouts of America v. James Dale Warped the Law of Free Association (Yale University Press 2009) Jack M. Balkin and Reva B. Siegel, The Constitution in 2020 (Oxford University Press 2009) Heather K. Gerken, The Democracy Index: Why Our Election System Is Failing and How to Fix It (Princeton University Press 2009) Mary Dudziak, Exporting American Dreams: Thurgood Marshall's African Journey (Oxford University Press 2008) David Luban, Legal Ethics and Human Dignity (Cambridge Univ. Press 2007) Ian Ayres, Super Crunchers: Why Thinking-By-Numbers is the New Way to be Smart (Bantam 2007) Jack M. Balkin, James Grimmelmann, Eddan Katz, Nimrod Kozlovski, Shlomit Wagman and Tal Zarsky, eds., Cybercrime: Digital Cops in a Networked Environment (N.Y.U. Press 2007) Jack M. Balkin and Beth Simone Noveck, The State of Play: Law, Games, and Virtual Worlds (N.Y.U. Press 2006) Andrew Koppelman, Same Sex, Different States: When Same-Sex Marriages Cross State Lines (Yale University Press 2006) Brian Tamanaha, Law as a Means to an End (Cambridge University Press 2006) Sanford Levinson, Our Undemocratic Constitution (Oxford University Press 2006) Mark Graber, Dred Scott and the Problem of Constitutional Evil (Cambridge University Press 2006) Jack M. Balkin, ed., What Roe v. Wade Should Have Said (N.Y.U. Press 2005) Sanford Levinson, ed., Torture: A Collection (Oxford University Press 2004) Balkin.com homepage Bibliography Conlaw.net Cultural Software Writings Opeds The Information Society Project BrownvBoard.com Useful Links Syllabi and Exams |