Balkinization   |
Balkinization
Balkinization Symposiums: A Continuing List                                                                E-mail: Jack Balkin: jackbalkin at yahoo.com Bruce Ackerman bruce.ackerman at yale.edu Ian Ayres ian.ayres at yale.edu Corey Brettschneider corey_brettschneider at brown.edu Mary Dudziak mary.l.dudziak at emory.edu Joey Fishkin joey.fishkin at gmail.com Heather Gerken heather.gerken at yale.edu Abbe Gluck abbe.gluck at yale.edu Mark Graber mgraber at law.umaryland.edu Stephen Griffin sgriffin at tulane.edu Jonathan Hafetz jonathan.hafetz at shu.edu Jeremy Kessler jkessler at law.columbia.edu Andrew Koppelman akoppelman at law.northwestern.edu Marty Lederman msl46 at law.georgetown.edu Sanford Levinson slevinson at law.utexas.edu David Luban david.luban at gmail.com Gerard Magliocca gmaglioc at iupui.edu Jason Mazzone mazzonej at illinois.edu Linda McClain lmcclain at bu.edu John Mikhail mikhail at law.georgetown.edu Frank Pasquale pasquale.frank at gmail.com Nate Persily npersily at gmail.com Michael Stokes Paulsen michaelstokespaulsen at gmail.com Deborah Pearlstein dpearlst at yu.edu Rick Pildes rick.pildes at nyu.edu David Pozen dpozen at law.columbia.edu Richard Primus raprimus at umich.edu K. Sabeel Rahmansabeel.rahman at brooklaw.edu Alice Ristroph alice.ristroph at shu.edu Neil Siegel siegel at law.duke.edu David Super david.super at law.georgetown.edu Brian Tamanaha btamanaha at wulaw.wustl.edu Nelson Tebbe nelson.tebbe at brooklaw.edu Mark Tushnet mtushnet at law.harvard.edu Adam Winkler winkler at ucla.edu Compendium of posts on Hobby Lobby and related cases The Anti-Torture Memos: Balkinization Posts on Torture, Interrogation, Detention, War Powers, and OLC The Anti-Torture Memos (arranged by topic) Recent Posts Historical Empiricism and the Schleicher Trilemma
|
Wednesday, May 31, 2023
Historical Empiricism and the Schleicher Trilemma
Guest Blogger
For the Balkinization symposium on David Schleicher, In a Bad State: Responding to State and Local Budget Crises (Oxford University Press, 2023). Vince Buccola The
principal object of David Schleicher’s slim, new book, In a Bad State, is
to set out a conceptual schema for mapping policy options with respect to state
and local financial distress. The Schleicher Trilemma states that no policy
response can simultaneously vindicate each of three commonsense values that
(national) political actors are apt to hold, and the book is devoted to
elaborating this core insight. There is much more to the work, of course. As anyone
who knows Schleicher even a bit will expect, the book’s 171 pages (sans notes)
brim with fascinating data and anecdotes. (Schleicher aficionados will,
however, be disappointed not to find an index entry for “Stillman, Whit.”) By
word count, much of the book (pp. 33–117) is historical. Schleicher offers a
fresh account of each major wave of state and local financial distress in the
United States, from the aftermath of the Revolutionary War through Covid-19.
The historical vignettes alone more than justify the cover price. In the
context of the book’s analytical purpose, though, they serve didactic and
argumentative functions, on one hand to illustrate the Trilemma through
real-world application and on the other to verify the causal relationships it
posits.
The Schleicher
Trilemma turns on a mismatch between policy levers and policy goals. In
Schleicher’s typology, there are three generic strategies national policy can pursue
in relation to local (in which category I’ll include state) government
financial distress. The national government can (1) bail out the local government
and its creditors; (2) encourage the local government to default on its
creditors; or (3) force the local government to pursue an austerity path—raising
taxes, cutting spending—to pay its creditors. And there are three generic
political values at stake. National policy makers will want to (A) reduce moral
hazard (for future leaders of, and lenders to, local governments); (B)
encourage future lending to local governments (to further infrastructure
investment); and (C) avoid social fallout from local collapse of services or
tax hikes. The rub is that each policy attitude sacrifices one of the values. The
choices are A(2,3), B(1,3), or C(1,2). It is
a tremendous heuristic. Like all great heuristics, it manages simultaneously to
encompass the wide universe of relevant possibility and to be, for lack of a
better word, true. One doesn’t need to indulge game-theoretic axioms or harbor
an unrealistic notion of rational expectations to see that the trade-offs Schleicher
posits are inevitable. Grasping them is fundamental for those interested in the
connection between national policy and state and local investment, and I
therefore predict that In a Bad State will long prove a starting point
in policy analysis of local financial distress in the same way that
Modigliani-Miller is still the beginning of interesting questions in corporate
finance. Having
just said that Schleicher’s historical vignettes are largely illustrative, I hesitate
to devote 1500 words to quibbling about the municipal bond cases. But I’ll do
so anyway in service of a larger thought about the relationship between
politico-economic theories, such as the Schleicher Trilemma, and historical
empiricism. My conclusion is that Schleicher’s characterization of the
municipal bond cases is debatable, but that it doesn’t detract from the praise
I have already lavished on the Trilemma. The
second half of the nineteenth century saw repeated waves of distress in Midwestern
and Western cities and counties. Infrastructure financed by long-dated bonds,
especially railroads, failed to generate the revenues promoters had hoped for
and led to widespread budgetary (and other) problems. Hundreds of
municipalities repudiated their bonds, arguing that they had been issued ultra
vires and that the holders, capitalists in Europe and the American Northeast,
weren’t owed a dime. Litigation in the federal courts was frequent, with
several hundred disputes reaching the Supreme Court between 1859–1899. Schleicher
characterizes the period as an episode of local financial distress in which
national political actors—a stable majority of justices of the Supreme Court—chose
to force austerity (pp. 41–56). In his words, “[t]he Court effectively served
as the enforcer of part of the federal government’s pro-railroad policy” (p.
52). So characterized, the municipal bond cases help to establish the Schleicher
Trilemma as an empirical fact. By forcing local governments to pay their debts
(without assistance from the national government), Schleicher concludes, the
justices caused near-term hardship in the locations forced to pay but also preserved
capitalists’ willingness to lend, and thus helped to bring forth a subsequent
era in which municipal infrastructure projects flourished while moral hazard
was cabined. To me
the characterization rings only half right. I’ll set aside my objection to
Schleicher casting the post-bellum justices as legally unbound agents
exercising a free hand in domestic financial policy. Whether the Court was the
kind of willful institution imagined by the Realists or instead largely adhered
to legal doctrine is irrelevant to the effects of the Court’s judgments on
local finance. My relevant objection is to the notion that the Court’s
decisions collectively should be described as having forced an austerity path
on would-be repudiators. Three points to note: First,
the Court allowed many municipalities to repudiate. Allison Buccola and I coded
every Supreme Court decision testing the validity of a municipal bond between
1859–1899. We found that the Court ruled
for the repudiating municipality in fully one-third of the
unique validity cases (57 out of 172).
As early as 1860, in just the second railroad-bond case
to reach the Court,
the justices concluded that a bond would be held unenforceable, even in the
hands of a bona fide purchaser, if it had been issued without valid legislative
authorization or if any statutory conditions on issuance had not been satisfied
(and the issuer was not estopped by its own representations to the contrary).
To be sure, the ratio of wins and losses was not constant over the period. Municipalities
prevailed in just one of fifteen cases of repudiation between 1859-1869 and in
almost half of the cases after 1879. One could make out a debatable case that some
of the decisions in the 1860s were especially momentous, on account of the
generality of their rationales, or especially willful, on account of
their inconsistency with prevailing legal principles. But the justices’
willingness in the right case to tell investors to take a zero is hardly what
one would expect from devoted champions of capital. Second,
the Court did not go as far as it might have in providing a remedy to
disappointed bondholders. To hold a bond valid—to say that it could not be
repudiated—was only the first step in forcing austerity. Unless bondholders
have a practically realizable way to collect, a local government that prefers
to default can do whether or not courts hold the bond valid. Schleicher correctly
notes that the Court took some bold remedial steps (pp. 49–50). In Knox Couty v. Aspinwall, for example, the justices
held that federal courts could issue writs of mandamus to local
government officials, ordering them to impose taxes sufficient to pay valid
bonds. The justices went as far as to allow a federal court to appoint a
receiver to collect local tax where the relevant state law
explicitly authorized that remedy.
But the justices maintained a limited view of what federal courts could do in
respect of collection. They repeatedly held that federal courts had no equitable
power to impose a tax or appoint a receiver to do the
same or to collect
a tax validly imposed. These limits were immensely important, because they
allowed local officials to avoid actually paying valid bonds by dodging service
of mandamus or resigning office upon being served, two tactics
recalcitrant officials frequently employed (p. 50). The Court’s decisions thus were
some distance from imposing maximum austerity. Third,
the justices’ application of prevailing legal principles was not so obviously
result-oriented as Schleicher suggests. Schleicher, like many historians before
him, points to the infamous Gelpcke v. City of Dubuque as the prime example of
Supreme Court willfulness (pp. 45–48). Gelpcke held that bonds issued by
the city to fund local railroad construction were valid notwithstanding a
decision of the Iowa supreme court opining that the state constitution forbade
the legislation under which the bonds had been issued. Schleicher sees Gelpcke
as a marker of economic policy because it so obviously violated prevailing
legal principles. So strong was the justices’ will that “[l]egal niceties …
could not stop the Court from enforcing debts and protecting bondholders” (p.
48). In my view, though, Gelpcke is eminently defensible on purely
formal grounds. Justice Swayne’s opinion is regrettably opaque, leading
commentators over the years incorrectly to understand it as a perversion of Swift
v. Tyson or a confused application of the Constitution’s contracts clause.
But the decision ought rather to be read as standing for a (sensible) plausibility
limitation to the proposition that the justices will defer to a state
supreme court’s interpretation of its own state’s law. This is what Swayne
meant with his hyperbolic promise that the Court “shall never immolate truth,
justice, and the law, because a State tribunal has erected the altar and
decreed the sacrifice.” In Swayne’s view, to apply the logic of Wapello
would have been to “immolate” Iowa law. The Iowa constitution did not, in fact,
bar the legislature from allowing Dubuque to issue its bonds, whatever some
elected judges who had campaigned on a repudiation platform might say. And
Swayne was right. Wapello was implausible. No concrete provision in
Iowa’s constitution forbade public subsidy of infrastructure built by
corporations. The text was as blank on that score as every other state’s
constitution was. And the issue had been judicially decided many times, in many
states—including in eight decisions of the Iowa supreme court—over 30 years.
Unless one thinks the justices bound even by bad-faith decisions, for example
on a post-Erie-ish theory that what a state supreme court says about
state law just is the law, Gelpcke was not only reasonable but probably
correct. Do
these complications cast doubt on the validity of Schleicher’s schema? No, not
in the least, but because the kind of historical storytelling on offer, while
illuminating in many ways, can neither verify nor falsify the type of causal
account the Trilemma provides. The forces underlying the Trilemma are marginal
forces. Local governments’ propensity to default makes lenders less
willing to provide capital; their propensity to repay has the opposite effect;
bailouts made moral hazard worse. In each case, the effect is compared
to a counterfactual, hypothetical, ceteris paribus world. If
Schleicher’s characterization of the municipal bond cases is right—if, that is,
the Supreme Court’s decisions implemented a kind of austerity policy on
municipal governments—then the Trilemma says that local governments in the
1880s and 1890s, say, should have been able to borrow more cheaply than they
otherwise could have. What do we know about that claim? What can we know?
Schleicher points out that the last decades of the nineteenth century saw local
governments financing infrastructure projects on an outstanding scale. So they
did. But that compares the period to other times rather than to a different
version of the same time. The level of financial activity in Period n
alone can’t tell us anything about the policies implemented in n-1 or
about those policies’ marginal effects. To my
mind, a different kind of empiricism is called for. I accept, or better said admire,
the Schleicher Trilemma effectively a priori. The direction of the effects it
posits have to be right. What is left open are what we might call the
elasticities associated with each horn of the Trilemma. When a medium-sized
city facing financial distress gives its bondholders a fifty-cent haircut, how
much do the future borrowing costs of similarly situated governments increase?
(For that matter, which governments are similarly situated?) Questions like
these might be answerable and could help to calibrate Schleicher’s schema. Which
brings me to where I began. When David Schleicher publishes 170 pages about
state and local budget crises, it underscores the wisdom of the old adage that you
don’t have to have read a book to have an opinion on it. In a Bad State delivers
what I expect will for a long while be the organizing framework for serious
thought about local government financial distress. In that sense, Schleicher
leaves his readers In a Much Better State. Vince
Buccola is Associate Professor of Legal Studies & Business Ethics at The
Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania. Comments welcome: buccola@wharton.upenn.edu.
|
Books by Balkinization Bloggers Linda C. McClain and Aziza Ahmed, The Routledge Companion to Gender and COVID-19 (Routledge, 2024) David Pozen, The Constitution of the War on Drugs (Oxford University Press, 2024) Jack M. Balkin, Memory and Authority: The Uses of History in Constitutional Interpretation (Yale University Press, 2024) Mark A. Graber, Punish Treason, Reward Loyalty: The Forgotten Goals of Constitutional Reform after the Civil War (University of Kansas Press, 2023) Jack M. Balkin, What Roe v. Wade Should Have Said: The Nation's Top Legal Experts Rewrite America's Most Controversial Decision - Revised Edition (NYU Press, 2023) Andrew Koppelman, Burning Down the House: How Libertarian Philosophy Was Corrupted by Delusion and Greed (St. Martin’s Press, 2022) Gerard N. Magliocca, Washington's Heir: The Life of Justice Bushrod Washington (Oxford University Press, 2022) Joseph Fishkin and William E. Forbath, The Anti-Oligarchy Constitution: Reconstructing the Economic Foundations of American Democracy (Harvard University Press, 2022) Mark Tushnet and Bojan Bugaric, Power to the People: Constitutionalism in the Age of Populism (Oxford University Press 2021). Mark Philip Bradley and Mary L. Dudziak, eds., Making the Forever War: Marilyn B. Young on the Culture and Politics of American Militarism Culture and Politics in the Cold War and Beyond (University of Massachusetts Press, 2021). Jack M. Balkin, What Obergefell v. Hodges Should Have Said: The Nation's Top Legal Experts Rewrite America's Same-Sex Marriage Decision (Yale University Press, 2020) Frank Pasquale, New Laws of Robotics: Defending Human Expertise in the Age of AI (Belknap Press, 2020) Jack M. Balkin, The Cycles of Constitutional Time (Oxford University Press, 2020) Mark Tushnet, Taking Back the Constitution: Activist Judges and the Next Age of American Law (Yale University Press 2020). Andrew Koppelman, Gay Rights vs. Religious Liberty?: The Unnecessary Conflict (Oxford University Press, 2020) Ezekiel J Emanuel and Abbe R. Gluck, The Trillion Dollar Revolution: How the Affordable Care Act Transformed Politics, Law, and Health Care in America (PublicAffairs, 2020) Linda C. McClain, Who's the Bigot?: Learning from Conflicts over Marriage and Civil Rights Law (Oxford University Press, 2020) Sanford Levinson and Jack M. Balkin, Democracy and Dysfunction (University of Chicago Press, 2019) Sanford Levinson, Written in Stone: Public Monuments in Changing Societies (Duke University Press 2018) Mark A. Graber, Sanford Levinson, and Mark Tushnet, eds., Constitutional Democracy in Crisis? (Oxford University Press 2018) Gerard Magliocca, The Heart of the Constitution: How the Bill of Rights became the Bill of Rights (Oxford University Press, 2018) Cynthia Levinson and Sanford Levinson, Fault Lines in the Constitution: The Framers, Their Fights, and the Flaws that Affect Us Today (Peachtree Publishers, 2017) Brian Z. Tamanaha, A Realistic Theory of Law (Cambridge University Press 2017) Sanford Levinson, Nullification and Secession in Modern Constitutional Thought (University Press of Kansas 2016) Sanford Levinson, An Argument Open to All: Reading The Federalist in the 21st Century (Yale University Press 2015) Stephen M. Griffin, Broken Trust: Dysfunctional Government and Constitutional Reform (University Press of Kansas, 2015) Frank Pasquale, The Black Box Society: The Secret Algorithms That Control Money and Information (Harvard University Press, 2015) Bruce Ackerman, We the People, Volume 3: The Civil Rights Revolution (Harvard University Press, 2014) Balkinization Symposium on We the People, Volume 3: The Civil Rights Revolution Joseph Fishkin, Bottlenecks: A New Theory of Equal Opportunity (Oxford University Press, 2014) Mark A. Graber, A New Introduction to American Constitutionalism (Oxford University Press, 2013) John Mikhail, Elements of Moral Cognition: Rawls' Linguistic Analogy and the Cognitive Science of Moral and Legal Judgment (Cambridge University Press, 2013) Gerard N. Magliocca, American Founding Son: John Bingham and the Invention of the Fourteenth Amendment (New York University Press, 2013) Stephen M. Griffin, Long Wars and the Constitution (Harvard University Press, 2013) Andrew Koppelman, The Tough Luck Constitution and the Assault on Health Care Reform (Oxford University Press, 2013) James E. Fleming and Linda C. McClain, Ordered Liberty: Rights, Responsibilities, and Virtues (Harvard University Press, 2013) Balkinization Symposium on Ordered Liberty: Rights, Responsibilities, and Virtues Andrew Koppelman, Defending American Religious Neutrality (Harvard University Press, 2013) Brian Z. Tamanaha, Failing Law Schools (University of Chicago Press, 2012) Sanford Levinson, Framed: America's 51 Constitutions and the Crisis of Governance (Oxford University Press, 2012) Linda C. McClain and Joanna L. Grossman, Gender Equality: Dimensions of Women's Equal Citizenship (Cambridge University Press, 2012) Mary Dudziak, War Time: An Idea, Its History, Its Consequences (Oxford University Press, 2012) Jack M. Balkin, Living Originalism (Harvard University Press, 2011) Jason Mazzone, Copyfraud and Other Abuses of Intellectual Property Law (Stanford University Press, 2011) Richard W. Garnett and Andrew Koppelman, First Amendment Stories, (Foundation Press 2011) Jack M. Balkin, Constitutional Redemption: Political Faith in an Unjust World (Harvard University Press, 2011) Gerard Magliocca, The Tragedy of William Jennings Bryan: Constitutional Law and the Politics of Backlash (Yale University Press, 2011) Bernard Harcourt, The Illusion of Free Markets: Punishment and the Myth of Natural Order (Harvard University Press, 2010) Bruce Ackerman, The Decline and Fall of the American Republic (Harvard University Press, 2010) Balkinization Symposium on The Decline and Fall of the American Republic Ian Ayres. Carrots and Sticks: Unlock the Power of Incentives to Get Things Done (Bantam Books, 2010) Mark Tushnet, Why the Constitution Matters (Yale University Press 2010) Ian Ayres and Barry Nalebuff: Lifecycle Investing: A New, Safe, and Audacious Way to Improve the Performance of Your Retirement Portfolio (Basic Books, 2010) Jack M. Balkin, The Laws of Change: I Ching and the Philosophy of Life (2d Edition, Sybil Creek Press 2009) Brian Z. Tamanaha, Beyond the Formalist-Realist Divide: The Role of Politics in Judging (Princeton University Press 2009) Andrew Koppelman and Tobias Barrington Wolff, A Right to Discriminate?: How the Case of Boy Scouts of America v. James Dale Warped the Law of Free Association (Yale University Press 2009) Jack M. Balkin and Reva B. Siegel, The Constitution in 2020 (Oxford University Press 2009) Heather K. Gerken, The Democracy Index: Why Our Election System Is Failing and How to Fix It (Princeton University Press 2009) Mary Dudziak, Exporting American Dreams: Thurgood Marshall's African Journey (Oxford University Press 2008) David Luban, Legal Ethics and Human Dignity (Cambridge Univ. Press 2007) Ian Ayres, Super Crunchers: Why Thinking-By-Numbers is the New Way to be Smart (Bantam 2007) Jack M. Balkin, James Grimmelmann, Eddan Katz, Nimrod Kozlovski, Shlomit Wagman and Tal Zarsky, eds., Cybercrime: Digital Cops in a Networked Environment (N.Y.U. Press 2007) Jack M. Balkin and Beth Simone Noveck, The State of Play: Law, Games, and Virtual Worlds (N.Y.U. Press 2006) Andrew Koppelman, Same Sex, Different States: When Same-Sex Marriages Cross State Lines (Yale University Press 2006) Brian Tamanaha, Law as a Means to an End (Cambridge University Press 2006) Sanford Levinson, Our Undemocratic Constitution (Oxford University Press 2006) Mark Graber, Dred Scott and the Problem of Constitutional Evil (Cambridge University Press 2006) Jack M. Balkin, ed., What Roe v. Wade Should Have Said (N.Y.U. Press 2005) Sanford Levinson, ed., Torture: A Collection (Oxford University Press 2004) Balkin.com homepage Bibliography Conlaw.net Cultural Software Writings Opeds The Information Society Project BrownvBoard.com Useful Links Syllabi and Exams |