E-mail:
Jack Balkin: jackbalkin at yahoo.com
Bruce Ackerman bruce.ackerman at yale.edu
Ian Ayres ian.ayres at yale.edu
Corey Brettschneider corey_brettschneider at brown.edu
Mary Dudziak mary.l.dudziak at emory.edu
Joey Fishkin joey.fishkin at gmail.com
Heather Gerken heather.gerken at yale.edu
Abbe Gluck abbe.gluck at yale.edu
Mark Graber mgraber at law.umaryland.edu
Stephen Griffin sgriffin at tulane.edu
Jonathan Hafetz jonathan.hafetz at shu.edu
Jeremy Kessler jkessler at law.columbia.edu
Andrew Koppelman akoppelman at law.northwestern.edu
Marty Lederman msl46 at law.georgetown.edu
Sanford Levinson slevinson at law.utexas.edu
David Luban david.luban at gmail.com
Gerard Magliocca gmaglioc at iupui.edu
Jason Mazzone mazzonej at illinois.edu
Linda McClain lmcclain at bu.edu
John Mikhail mikhail at law.georgetown.edu
Frank Pasquale pasquale.frank at gmail.com
Nate Persily npersily at gmail.com
Michael Stokes Paulsen michaelstokespaulsen at gmail.com
Deborah Pearlstein dpearlst at yu.edu
Rick Pildes rick.pildes at nyu.edu
David Pozen dpozen at law.columbia.edu
Richard Primus raprimus at umich.edu
K. Sabeel Rahmansabeel.rahman at brooklaw.edu
Alice Ristroph alice.ristroph at shu.edu
Neil Siegel siegel at law.duke.edu
David Super david.super at law.georgetown.edu
Brian Tamanaha btamanaha at wulaw.wustl.edu
Nelson Tebbe nelson.tebbe at brooklaw.edu
Mark Tushnet mtushnet at law.harvard.edu
Adam Winkler winkler at ucla.edu
On Amendment Difficulty and Informal Constitutional Change
Stephen Griffin
Continuing
with these posts on the new originalism and living constitutionalism. The conventional approach or simple model of
the difficulty of amendment starts with the observation that Article V imposes
a high bar by requiring super-majorities to pass any formal amendment. At the same time, the existence of judicial
review creates an avenue by which the Constitution may be adapted to the
changing needs of society. Thus, the
simple model concludes, the difficulty of amendment results in the Constitution
changing “informally” through judicial interpretation. The simple model has two elements – amendment
difficulty due to formal rules and the backstop of judicial review allowing for
compensating informal change. Both are
implicitly assumed to be uniform across American history.
I do
not subscribe to the simple model.
Recently I have been cited for the view, expressed in a 1995 symposium
in Constitutional Commentary, that
Article V is the most regrettable feature of the Constitution. If I may interject a personal note, my view
is presented much more fully in my 1996 book American Constitutionalism: From Theory to Politics (and more
recently in Long Wars and the
Constitution). To describe my
approach in very general terms, I think we can make greater progress in
understanding amendment difficulty and informal constitutional change from a
historical point of view by consulting the extensive scholarship on state
building and American political development.
We can use this literature to focus attention on specific periods – call
them crises of constitutional change – that illuminate why the Constitution has
changed in recent times principally through non-Article V means rather than
formal amendments.
To
be sure, the theory of constitutional change I presented in AmericanConstitutionalism was over-complicated. For one thing, I explored at length the
possibility of understanding informal constitutional change by comparing the
state and federal experience. I’m not
sure that argument works so I wouldn’t make it today. Nevertheless, there were other features to
the theory I presented that are still worth considering. An elaboration and update of that theory
follows.
Unlike
the simple model, we should not assume that amendment difficulty is uniform
across US history. After all, the
founding generation approved twelve amendments in a relatively brief period. This points up that if Article V poses a
problem, it developed later in American history. It also suggests that the problem cannot be
attributed simply to the extra hurdle of a supermajority rule. Amendments have become more difficult over
time for a number of reasons, including the increase in the number of states
required to ratify and what political development scholars describe as the
thickening of political institutions.
Yet the true “amendment difficulty” lies elsewhere.
The real
genesis of the amendment difficulty argument is that no enacted (or even
proposed) amendment for decades has come anywhere close to embodying the constitutional
changes that have occurred, particularly since the New Deal, both in the powers
and structure of the federal government and the changed meaning of
constitutional rights. This is obviously
a contestable normative judgment, but one that is very widely shared over
diverse areas of constitutional law, including national regulatory power, race
and federalism, and national security. This
also points up, by the way, that the amendment difficulty argument itself is a product
of contemporary times and likely did not exist prior to the late nineteenth
century.
As a
side matter, I don’t agree that constitutional change through judicial review
is best conceptualized as “informal” if Supreme Court rulings can themselves be
overcome only through formal amendment.
To the extent that Court rulings have the same status as the text of the
Constitution (a somewhat contested point, I recognize), they should count at
least as quasi-formal aspects of our constitutional structure. But this is not to deny that informal
constitutional change does occur. Rather,
it has a different institutional home – namely, the branches and activities of
government not usually overseen by the Court.
This line of argument exposes a hidden implausible assumption of the
simple model – that the Court by itself can somehow modify any aspect of the
Constitution in order to keep it up to date.
That doesn’t work for war powers, for example, as I explore at length in
Long Wars and the Constitution.
The
contrast I develop in my theory is thus between the “legalized” (or
judicialized) Constitution – the original text plus valid amendments plus
judicial interpretation – and the “nonlegalized” or informal Constitution. The latter is now conceptualized by many
scholars as the “small-c” “unwritten” constitution, a notion inspired in part
by the British model of constitutional conventions. Although I considered the British model in my
early work, I later abandoned this line of inquiry when I realized it was
inconsistent with any sort of adherence to the status of the Constitution as
supreme law. This suggests the possibility,
often not considered by scholars who take inspiration from the British model, that
aspects of the “small-c” constitution could themselves come into conflict with
its “big-C” counterpart and so be rendered (or regarded) as invalid. War powers is again an example. Allowing, however, that the “small-c” concept
has a basis in reality, the critical question is still how to specify the
relationship between the two.
I’m
afraid most of this is by way of ground clearing, which means we need to
restart and restate the amendment difficulty argument. Recall that all the simple model offers is
the distinction between formal and informal change, the bare assertion that
judicial interpretation can account for all the informal change that has
occurred (even in areas such as presidential war powers where the Court has
never been consistently active), and the assumption that both of these elements
have been relatively uniform across American history. By contrast, I argue that while formal change
was an important element in adapting the Constitution to new circumstances into
the twentieth century, the difficulty of amendment increased substantially over
time. So the significant adaptations of
roughly the last eight decades have occurred solely through non-Article V means
(putting the point this way to avoid the assumption that judicial
interpretation has been the only means of adaptation).
This
way of posing the issue emphasizes the twentieth century, especially the New
Deal period, as the critical point at which we got off the Article V track
(originalists might well agree!). Within
that period, the issue should not be posed so much in terms of whether we constructively
amended the Constitution through judicial interpretation, but rather how we
should in general understand the problem of informal constitutional change. Leaving the simple model behind involves
appreciating the relevance of three questions: (1) how to conceptualize the
historical baseline against which constitutional change is measured; (2) why
change, particularly during the New Deal, did not (and probably could not)
occur through formal amendment; (3) how did constitutional change actually occur
– the mechanisms of change. In line with
my suggestion that the political development literature can be of great use
here, I contend that the overarching crucial issue is how to understand the
relationship between the formal, “big-C” Constitution and the development of
American state institutions. I’ll take
up these questions in my next post.