E-mail:
Jack Balkin: jackbalkin at yahoo.com
Bruce Ackerman bruce.ackerman at yale.edu
Ian Ayres ian.ayres at yale.edu
Corey Brettschneider corey_brettschneider at brown.edu
Mary Dudziak mary.l.dudziak at emory.edu
Joey Fishkin joey.fishkin at gmail.com
Heather Gerken heather.gerken at yale.edu
Abbe Gluck abbe.gluck at yale.edu
Mark Graber mgraber at law.umaryland.edu
Stephen Griffin sgriffin at tulane.edu
Jonathan Hafetz jonathan.hafetz at shu.edu
Jeremy Kessler jkessler at law.columbia.edu
Andrew Koppelman akoppelman at law.northwestern.edu
Marty Lederman msl46 at law.georgetown.edu
Sanford Levinson slevinson at law.utexas.edu
David Luban david.luban at gmail.com
Gerard Magliocca gmaglioc at iupui.edu
Jason Mazzone mazzonej at illinois.edu
Linda McClain lmcclain at bu.edu
John Mikhail mikhail at law.georgetown.edu
Frank Pasquale pasquale.frank at gmail.com
Nate Persily npersily at gmail.com
Michael Stokes Paulsen michaelstokespaulsen at gmail.com
Deborah Pearlstein dpearlst at yu.edu
Rick Pildes rick.pildes at nyu.edu
David Pozen dpozen at law.columbia.edu
Richard Primus raprimus at umich.edu
K. Sabeel Rahmansabeel.rahman at brooklaw.edu
Alice Ristroph alice.ristroph at shu.edu
Neil Siegel siegel at law.duke.edu
David Super david.super at law.georgetown.edu
Brian Tamanaha btamanaha at wulaw.wustl.edu
Nelson Tebbe nelson.tebbe at brooklaw.edu
Mark Tushnet mtushnet at law.harvard.edu
Adam Winkler winkler at ucla.edu
Lisa
and Amy have put together what will surely be a fantastic conference on
Innovation Law Beyond IP.I have
been lucky enough to be assigned to comment on two wonderful papers on prizes
and grants, the first by Michael Burstein and Fiona Murray, and the second by
Bhaven Sampat.The papers are both
interesting in their own right and thought-provoking in combination, and I will
offer some brief comments on both fronts here.
To
my knowledge, Burstein and Murray’s in-depth examination of the Progressive
Insurance Automotive X Prize (PIAXP) is the first of its kind.Their research yields (at least) two
unexpected and deeply important findings.The first is the importance of process over substance.Burstein and Murray observe that the
rules for the PIAXP were not fully fleshed out when the competition began, and
that organizers made regular and significant changes to many of the guidelines
surrounding the prize.This
included splitting the competition into multiple divisions based upon
automobile type, a major alteration if ever there was one.Yet only a few disgruntled participants
left the competition; the vast majority remained and competed until they were
eliminated.Burstein and Murray
document how the process of changing the rules was viewed by participants as
legitimate and inclusive, and they argue that this legitimacy held the
competition together despite the frequent substantive rule changes
themselves.An important question
going forward is whether fair process will effectively inoculate substantive
changes when the prize involves far-flung corporate competitors in an
arms-length marketplace.As is the
case with respect to property regimes, the lessons that apply when competitors
are members of a closer-knit
community may not hold true when competitors are profit-maximizing rivals.
Second, and relatedly, Burstein and
Murray correctly demonstrate the importance of the PIAXP participants’ motivations.It seems evident that for most of the
participants, something other than the money itself—the reputational gains from
winning an X-Prize, the IP, or even simply the research challenge—must have
been the primary motivation for entering.For most participants, the net present value of competing is negative.Again, going forward, it will be
interesting to see whether this approach will scale.When the majority of competitors for innovation prizes are
for-profit firms, and the prizes are worth far more in financial than reputational
terms, the prize rules and governance structures might assume greater
importance.Firms will be
reluctant to invest significant capital chasing a prize unless they can be
certain that the rules of the game are favorable from the outset (and will
remain so).Again, it may be that
process will no longer substitute for substance in the formation of those
rules.This only heightens the
concern that Burstein and Murray raise: the institutions offering prizes must
pay close attention to the governance structures surrounding those prizes.
Bhaven
Sampat’s fascinating paper Serendipity
concerns a related subject: NIH grant funding.Sampat’s research question is whether a large percentage of
medical developments really are serendipitous and unexpected, as popular
conceptions often have it.The
study he designs to answer this question is clever and yet highly
intuitive.Sampat connects NIH grants
with the medical publications that they generated by coding the grants
mentioned in the publication.He
then connects publications with patents by looking to see which publications
are cited as references by which patents.Finally, he connects patents to FDA-approved drugs via the Orange
Book.The result is a trail that
leads from NIH grants all the way to commercially available
pharmaceuticals.By classifying
the grants, publications, patents, and drugs by medical field, or even by type
of disease, Sampat can determine what percentage of drugs spring from grants
that were at least nominally directed at a different field of medicine.His results are striking.Across a number of different empirical
specifications, Sampat finds that at
minimum 30% of new drugs appear to have resulted from serendipitous
discoveries.
A
perplexing question raised by Sampat’s work is one that he acknowledges: are
these discoveries truly serendipitous or actually strategic?That is, perhaps researchers are
applying for grants in a given field for the same reason that Willie Sutton
robbed banks—because that’s where the money is—while nonetheless intending to
do research and make advances in a cognate field.Sampat notes that his data cannot answer this question, but
in truth the answer might not matter.Whether the NIH grants are yielding unexpected results, or whether they
are merely serving as a minor transactional impediment to scientists who know
what they want to study but must strategically frame their grant applications,
the point is that the grants are generating valuable medical research in areas
that the funding agencies never contemplated.The rules set by the funding agencies are not nearly so
restrictive or directive as they might think.
Sampat’s
work in turn poses questions for Burstein and Murray.Sampat calls into question the necessity, or the
effectiveness, of trying to centrally direct research through funding rules.Maybe the only objective should be to
get money in the hands of researchers and let them get to work.This in turn raises the question of how
important it is to properly specify the governance regime for a non-IP mechanism
of funding innovation.Perhaps it
is less important that the organizers of a prize, or a grant, get the rules
“right” than that there be rules—any set of rules—that will induce
participation.On the other hand,
it may be that the construction of a set of rules seen as fair and achievable
is itself the greatest challenge within a grant or prize regime.These two papers are engaged in an
important conversation on that topic, one which I expect (and hope) will play a
central role in this excellent conference.
Jonathan Masur is a professor of law at the University of Chicago. He can be reached at jmasur at uchicago.edu