E-mail:
Jack Balkin: jackbalkin at yahoo.com
Bruce Ackerman bruce.ackerman at yale.edu
Ian Ayres ian.ayres at yale.edu
Corey Brettschneider corey_brettschneider at brown.edu
Mary Dudziak mary.l.dudziak at emory.edu
Joey Fishkin joey.fishkin at gmail.com
Heather Gerken heather.gerken at yale.edu
Abbe Gluck abbe.gluck at yale.edu
Mark Graber mgraber at law.umaryland.edu
Stephen Griffin sgriffin at tulane.edu
Jonathan Hafetz jonathan.hafetz at shu.edu
Jeremy Kessler jkessler at law.columbia.edu
Andrew Koppelman akoppelman at law.northwestern.edu
Marty Lederman msl46 at law.georgetown.edu
Sanford Levinson slevinson at law.utexas.edu
David Luban david.luban at gmail.com
Gerard Magliocca gmaglioc at iupui.edu
Jason Mazzone mazzonej at illinois.edu
Linda McClain lmcclain at bu.edu
John Mikhail mikhail at law.georgetown.edu
Frank Pasquale pasquale.frank at gmail.com
Nate Persily npersily at gmail.com
Michael Stokes Paulsen michaelstokespaulsen at gmail.com
Deborah Pearlstein dpearlst at yu.edu
Rick Pildes rick.pildes at nyu.edu
David Pozen dpozen at law.columbia.edu
Richard Primus raprimus at umich.edu
K. Sabeel Rahmansabeel.rahman at brooklaw.edu
Alice Ristroph alice.ristroph at shu.edu
Neil Siegel siegel at law.duke.edu
David Super david.super at law.georgetown.edu
Brian Tamanaha btamanaha at wulaw.wustl.edu
Nelson Tebbe nelson.tebbe at brooklaw.edu
Mark Tushnet mtushnet at law.harvard.edu
Adam Winkler winkler at ucla.edu
Should a government ever make a firm
liable for failing to innovate,
instead of rewarding it for developing a new invention or information
good?This issue has received
almost no attention in the existing innovation literature, which focuses almost
exclusively on carrots, or opportunities to gain rewards.The most commonly discussed carrots are
IP rights, grants, and prizes.I’m
absurdly excited for the conference this weekend, in part because of the wealth
of papers on long-neglected reward mechanisms, including R&D tax credits, commercialization awards, public-private R&D partnerships, and public arts infrastructure.
Our contribution to the conference
takes a different tack.We argue
that we should broaden our view to consider the role not only of carrots but
also of sticks -- or potential penalties for failure to innovate – in
innovation policy.Why consider
sticks?For one, they’re already
in use.We offer several examples,
the most prominent being the Federal Corporate Average Fuel Economy (CAFE)
standards.CAFE standards create
penalties for car companies whose fleets fail to meet fuel efficiency standards
that increase over time, and are set by regulators who have long seen them as
“technology forcing.”Credible
studies have concluded that the CAFE program has had positive effects,
including by inducing innovation to improve fuel efficiency.In the paper, we also describe several
other innovation sticks, such as tort liability for failure to test, and
maximum speed limit penalties applied to states.
If innovation sticks exist, why have
they been difficult to see?And what
are their possible benefits and limits?A full explanation is available in our draft paper (email us for a copy
– it is in early stages yet).By
way of sneak preview, we think that innovation sticks are difficult to see from
existing theoretical accounts, because sticks cannot perform one function that
is often assumed essential in the IP and information economics literature –
they cannot compensate parties for their investment in information production.But as we describe, sticks can be used to
complement carrots (as is the case with CAFE), for example to help correct for
market failures that traditional exclusionary carrots cannot adequately
address.Sticks can also be used
in lieu of carrots – and be superior to carrots – under specific circumstances.
Sticks can be less costly than
carrots because in equilibrium they do not need to be paid, and so may produce
fewer price distortions.Of
course, sticks also have drawbacks. Governments designing sticks need a good
deal of information. And in the long run sticks may lead to exit from an
industry if they exacerbate an under-compensation problem. If we want to avoid the nirvana-fallacy, though, we should compare the problems of
sticks to the problems of their alternatives.Sometimes governments are reasonably well informed. And the
under-compensation problem that is assumed by the conventional literature is,
we argue, less extensive that that account suggests.
We think that under
some circumstances innovation sticks can play valuable role in our innovation
policy.We also offer a
proof-of-concept model of an innovation stick that could be applied to the
problem of car fatalities.Innovation
sticks could, we suggest, play a role in reducing national auto fatalities by
as much 20%.
Amy Kapczynski is an associate professor law at Yale. She can be reached at amy.kapczynski at yale.edu