E-mail:
Jack Balkin: jackbalkin at yahoo.com
Bruce Ackerman bruce.ackerman at yale.edu
Ian Ayres ian.ayres at yale.edu
Corey Brettschneider corey_brettschneider at brown.edu
Mary Dudziak mary.l.dudziak at emory.edu
Joey Fishkin joey.fishkin at gmail.com
Heather Gerken heather.gerken at yale.edu
Abbe Gluck abbe.gluck at yale.edu
Mark Graber mgraber at law.umaryland.edu
Stephen Griffin sgriffin at tulane.edu
Jonathan Hafetz jonathan.hafetz at shu.edu
Jeremy Kessler jkessler at law.columbia.edu
Andrew Koppelman akoppelman at law.northwestern.edu
Marty Lederman msl46 at law.georgetown.edu
Sanford Levinson slevinson at law.utexas.edu
David Luban david.luban at gmail.com
Gerard Magliocca gmaglioc at iupui.edu
Jason Mazzone mazzonej at illinois.edu
Linda McClain lmcclain at bu.edu
John Mikhail mikhail at law.georgetown.edu
Frank Pasquale pasquale.frank at gmail.com
Nate Persily npersily at gmail.com
Michael Stokes Paulsen michaelstokespaulsen at gmail.com
Deborah Pearlstein dpearlst at yu.edu
Rick Pildes rick.pildes at nyu.edu
David Pozen dpozen at law.columbia.edu
Richard Primus raprimus at umich.edu
K. Sabeel Rahmansabeel.rahman at brooklaw.edu
Alice Ristroph alice.ristroph at shu.edu
Neil Siegel siegel at law.duke.edu
David Super david.super at law.georgetown.edu
Brian Tamanaha btamanaha at wulaw.wustl.edu
Nelson Tebbe nelson.tebbe at brooklaw.edu
Mark Tushnet mtushnet at law.harvard.edu
Adam Winkler winkler at ucla.edu
On Sunday, March 30, the Yale Law School Information Society
Project is hosting a conference on Innovation Law
Beyond IP. To expand the discussion beyond our one day in New Haven,
participants will be blogging here over the coming weeks with some initial
thoughts on the conference papers, and more broadly on how we should define our
field as scholars as innovation. To kick off this symposium, I’ll say a bit
about the article I’m presenting, Beyond the Patents–Prizes Debate (coauthored with Daniel
Hemel and recently published in the Texas
Law Review), and how it fits with the broader conference agenda.
So far, intellectual property law has been the primary legal
field in which we think about both technical and creative innovation. For
example, Dan Burk and Mark Lemley (both of whom will be at our conference!) have
said that “[p]atent law is our
primary tool to promote innovation,” and they and other patent scholars
have spent a lot of time thinking about ways to better promote innovation
through patent law.
Not everyone thinks that patent law is the best way to provide
financial rewards for innovation, and there is an old debate about whether we
would be better off rewarding innovation through prizes. This debate continues
to have terrific new contributions, such as by Michael
Abramowicz (also attending our conference) and by Michael Burstein and
Fiona Murray (who will be blogging about their new prizes paper soon), and
prizes are also gaining ground in the popularpress.
There is also some literature on financially supporting innovation through
direct government spending with grants or procurement contracts, and our
conference will include three new papers in this area by Bhaven Sampat, Camilla
Hrdy, and Jim Bessen.
But with a few exceptions (such as work by Brett Frischmann, who will also be
at our conference), Daniel and I argue that this debate has ignored the role of
tax incentives for innovation, even though these are already important
innovation policies. I think Rob Merges summed up the view of IP scholars when
he recently wrote: “Taxation
is, of course, external to IP law.” I have also previously blogged about
how the Federal
Circuit ignores tax when discussing innovation policy. And yet R&D tax
incentives are already major innovation policies: IRC § 174 (which
allows companies to deduct expenses immediately rather than over a period of
future years) and § 41
(which provides a tax credit for companies that increase their R&D spending)
alone cost taxpayers over $10 billion per year.
In Beyond the
Patents–Prizes Debate, Daniel and I have tried to situate tax into our
innovation policy discussion and to create a coherent framework for thinking
about the innovation policy choice. We begin by explaining that in a
theoretical world where we could perfectly tailor each incentive, each of the
four main tools for rewarding innovators—patents, prizes, grants, and R&D
tax incentives—has the same cost to society (bracketing deadweight loss and
administrative costs). If the gap between the expected cost of an R&D
project and the return for the researcher absent government intervention is $1,
and the probability of success is 1-in-10, we can give innovators a $1 grant or
tax credit, or we can give a $10 prize or patent if the project is successful,
and for economically motivated rational actors with no risk aversion, these are
equivalent.
Of course, the real world is different from this theoretical
world in many important ways, and we think our framework is useful for figuring
out how different real-world considerations point toward different innovation
policy tools. In particular, we argue that every government transfer to spur
innovation embodies answers to three distinct questions (see pages 333 and 348
of our article for 2x2 and 2x2x2
illustrations of these dimensions):
(1) Who decides the size of the transfer? Does the
government tailor the reward on a project-by-project basis, or does it simply
establish general ground rules? Grants and fixed prizes are effective when the
government can foresee a potential invention and evaluate its costs and
benefits. Patents, in contrast, can leverage private information about
potential R&D projects, and we explain that technology-neutral tax incentives
can replicate these benefit.
(2) When is the reward transferred: before the results of
the research are known, or only ex post to successful projects? Ex post rewards
such as patents and prizes provide a strong incentive for success, but in some cases
that incentive might be dulled because ex post rewards are both delayed and
speculative, and innovators might be more responsive to a $1 tax credit or
grant today than to a 1-in-10 chance of a $10 patent or prize in the future.
(3) Who pays for the transfer: all taxpayers, or only users
of the resulting technology? Here, patents look different in that they are
generally paid for by users of the resulting technology (through
supracompetitive prices on patented products), rather than by all taxpayers. We
argue that whether the “user pays” aspect of patents is normatively attractive
will vary with the technology, and that in theory, “user pays” could be
incorporated into other reward mechanisms.
We walk through each of these considerations in much more detail
in our article, and we suggest that these questions can help guide policymakers
who are searching for the optimal solution to a particular innovation-related
problem. But whatever you think of our specific conclusions, our broader claim
is that tax law ought to be part of our innovation law conversation.
I think many of the most interesting IP law questions today
similarly lie at the intersection of IP and related fields. As we explain in
our conference
description, IP law is only one of many legal institutions that can help
promote, stifle, or govern knowledge production. In addition to transferring rewards
to innovators through tax incentives, grants, and prizes, governments regulate
innovation through the administrative state, creates legal rules and
infrastructures that can help sustain or undermine commons-based production,
and influence innovation through law and institutions related to immigration,
tort law, education, and more. I very much look forward to hearing more
thoughts on these topics over the coming weeks, both from conference
participants and from the broader innovation law community!
Lisa Larrimore Ouellette is a fellow at the Information Society Project. You can reach her by email at larrimore at gmail.com. Posted
10:53 AM
by Guest Blogger [link]