E-mail:
Jack Balkin: jackbalkin at yahoo.com
Bruce Ackerman bruce.ackerman at yale.edu
Ian Ayres ian.ayres at yale.edu
Corey Brettschneider corey_brettschneider at brown.edu
Mary Dudziak mary.l.dudziak at emory.edu
Joey Fishkin joey.fishkin at gmail.com
Heather Gerken heather.gerken at yale.edu
Abbe Gluck abbe.gluck at yale.edu
Mark Graber mgraber at law.umaryland.edu
Stephen Griffin sgriffin at tulane.edu
Jonathan Hafetz jonathan.hafetz at shu.edu
Jeremy Kessler jkessler at law.columbia.edu
Andrew Koppelman akoppelman at law.northwestern.edu
Marty Lederman msl46 at law.georgetown.edu
Sanford Levinson slevinson at law.utexas.edu
David Luban david.luban at gmail.com
Gerard Magliocca gmaglioc at iupui.edu
Jason Mazzone mazzonej at illinois.edu
Linda McClain lmcclain at bu.edu
John Mikhail mikhail at law.georgetown.edu
Frank Pasquale pasquale.frank at gmail.com
Nate Persily npersily at gmail.com
Michael Stokes Paulsen michaelstokespaulsen at gmail.com
Deborah Pearlstein dpearlst at yu.edu
Rick Pildes rick.pildes at nyu.edu
David Pozen dpozen at law.columbia.edu
Richard Primus raprimus at umich.edu
K. Sabeel Rahmansabeel.rahman at brooklaw.edu
Alice Ristroph alice.ristroph at shu.edu
Neil Siegel siegel at law.duke.edu
David Super david.super at law.georgetown.edu
Brian Tamanaha btamanaha at wulaw.wustl.edu
Nelson Tebbe nelson.tebbe at brooklaw.edu
Mark Tushnet mtushnet at law.harvard.edu
Adam Winkler winkler at ucla.edu
In my previous post, I laid out the outlines of a critique of demand-side theories of judicial behavior—of which Jack and Sandy’s theory is one—and suggested that they were insufficient without an account of the supply-side influences on legal change. Where demand-side theories emphasize what voters (influenced by popular movements) want, supply-side theories (like my book, The Rise of the Conservative Legal Movement) draw our attention to what the political class supplies. Supply-side theories understand political outcomes as importantly shaped by the activities of competing elites. In electoral politics, for example, supply-side theories argue that an adequate explanation must take account of the forces that determine who runs for office, not just with the choices voters make between ambitious office-holders. The best popular presentation of the supply-side electoral theory is Alan Ehrenhalt’s The United States of Ambition. If one party is able to durably present more attractive, better funded or more strategically savvy candidates, over time they will win more offices, controlling for popular preferences, than the party that is relatively lacking in such candidates.
Where my last post drew attention to the importance of supply-side factors in explaining judicial appointments—the key moving part in Jack and Sandy’s theory—this post moves our attention to a factor that they do not give much attention to, which is the court’s agenda.
Appointment-driven theories like theirs typically assume that the most important variable in explaining legal change is the preferences of judges, on the assumption that (judges’) demand produces its own supply. Now, of course, judges do have very important tools for shaping their agenda. First, they have almost complete negative agenda control, through their ability to deny cert. Second, judges have considerable tools for signaling their eagerness to hear certain kinds of claims in the future.
That said, the assumption that the Court’s agenda is driven (except in a negative sense) almost exclusively by the preferences of its members is clearly flawed. Charles Epp summed up the problem with this claim in his powerful book The Rights Revolution, where he argued that:
Many discussions of the relationship between the Supreme Court and litigants assume that the resources necessary to support litigation are easily generated and that, as a result, litigants of all kinds have always stood ready to bring forward any kind of case that the Court might indicate a willingness to hear or decide. But that presumes a pluralism of litigating interests and an evenness of the litigation playing field that is wholly unjustified. Not every issue is now, nor has been in the past, the subject of extensive litigation in lower courts, due in part to limitations in the availability of resources for legal mobilization.
Litigation is expensive, time consuming, complex, uncertain, and requires a very high level of ongoing organization. Especially where strategic litigation is concerned—litigation that seeks more than a “one-shot” victory in court—success requires the existence of highly motivated, specialized lawyers with a reliable base of funding, who are connected to a broad network of experts in other professions, lawyers willing to be local counsel, academics, and organizations able to provide strategic advice and assistance in identifying clients and cases. Those lawyers must be sufficiently shrewd that they can identify cases with the potential to put their issues in the best light, and to do so (in many cases) repeatedly, in order to generate circuit splits.
Without these sorts of resources, cases that members of the Court would be willing to hear, and would consider sympathetically, will either not reach their door, or will do so in a form that would produce less than the maximum return on the opportunity presented by a particular set of Justices’ preferences.
What is just as important, the litigation piece of the supply-side theory notes that even well-trained justices don’t always know precisely what it is they want, or how far they can legitimately take their own preferences. Usually Justices determine this in part by “feeling around” in the cases that are presented to them.Justices who operate in an environment in which they are constantly being fed well-designed cases that encourage them to consider ever-more-extreme implications of their existing preferences will produce more radical outputs than those who are not given those opportunities.
So, to sum up, the electoral, demand-side, theory of legal change is incomplete in failing to take account of the supply-side constraints on judicial appointments, and on the character of the Court’s agenda. In my third posting, I will identify a final component of the supply-side theory of legal change, which concerns the role of legitimating ideas.
I could not find enough meat on this part 2 bone to gnaw on. Perhaps part 3 will be more inviting. In the meantime, Legal Theory Blog posts today an interesting Abstract of an article by Sean Wilson titled "On the Problems of Political Science and the Nonsense of Quantitative Ideology Models" that appears to examine judicial politics.